Are life insurance holdings related to financial vulnerabilities?
Bernheim, B. Douglas ; Carman, Katherine Grace ; Jagadeesh, Gokhale 等
I. INTRODUCTION
The purpose of this article is to examine life insurance holdings
and financial vulnerabilities among couples over the life cycle. Two
separate concerns motivate our analysis. First, there are reasons to
suspect that life insurance coverage is poorly correlated with
underlying financial vulnerabilities. A well-known insurance industry
adage holds that life insurance is sold and not bought. Alternatively,
households may purchase long-term policies relatively early in life and
subsequently fail to adjust coverage appropriately because of inertia or
other psychological considerations. Second, households that purchase
little or no life insurance may leave either or both spouses at risk of
serious financial consequences.
With respect to the first concern, the available evidence is
limited. Using a sample of older workers drawn from the 1992 wave of the
Health and Retirement Study (HRS), Bernheim et al. (2003) documented a
startling mismatch between life insurance holdings and underlying
vulnerabilities (defined as the decline in living standard that a
survivor would experience in the absence of insurance). In particular,
they found virtually no correlation between these two variables.
However, because the HRS focuses on individuals approaching retirement,
this finding did not permit them to distinguish between the two
hypotheses mentioned in the previous paragraph.
The second concern has received considerably more attention. One
branch of the literature examines the experience of widows. Holden et
al. (1986) and Hurd and Wise (1989) documented sharp declines in living
standards and increases in poverty rates (from 9%, to 35%) among women
whose husbands actually passed away. A second branch of the literature
projects the consequences of widowhood for married individuals.
Analyzing data gathered during the 1960s from households in middle age
through early retirement, Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987; 1991a; 1991b)
found that roughly one-third of wives and secondary earners would have
seen their living standards decline by 25% or more had their spouses
died. Bernheim et al. (2003) adopted a similar approach but used more
recent, high-quality data, more accurate estimates of
survival--contingent income streams, and a more elaborate life-cycle
simulation model. They documented significant underlying vulnerabilities
among older working couples; ignoring life insurance, one-third of
secondary earners would have experienced significant (20% or greater)
declines in living standards had their spouses died in 1992, whereas
one-fifth would have experienced severe declines (40% or greater). More
important, only one in three households in these at-risk populations
held sufficient life insurance to avert significant or severe financial
consequences. Though primary earners (typically husbands) were less
frequently at risk for significant or severe consequences, they
generally had much less protection (insurance on the secondary
earner's life) for any given level of risk exposure. Notably, none
of the studies mentioned examined uninsured exposures among younger
households. This is a significant omission, because younger couples
generally have more contingent income to protect and hence greater
underlying vulnerabilities.
In the current study, we reexamine both sets of issues using data
obtained from the 1995 wave of the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF).
Relative to the HRS (studied by Bernheim et al., 2003), the primary
advantage of the SCF is that it includes adult respondents of all ages.
Consequently, we extend the existing literature by examining financial
vulnerabilities and life insurance coverage at all stages of the life
cycle. This permits us to provide the first available evidence
concerning uninsured financial vulnerabilities among young households,
as well as to distinguish between the two alternative explanations for
the absence of a correlation between financial vulnerabilities and
insurance holdings mentioned--that insurance bears little relation to
needs at the time of purchase and that households purchase long-term
contracts with initially appropriate insurance coverage but fail to
adjust this coverage through time as their circumstances change.
Because the SCF data are in some ways less comprehensive than the
HRS data, this extension comes at a cost. Most notably. matching Social
Security earnings histories are not available for the SCF sample. In
addition, certain measurement problems (e.g., the likelihood that a
nonworking widow or widower will enter the labor force or the potential
for remarriage) are more severe for younger households than for older
households. Nevertheless, because the SCF does contain information on
many important factors that determine financial vulnerabilities, it is
reasonable to infer that measured and actual financial vulnerabilities
are correlated. If households respond to greater financial
vulnerabilities by purchasing more insurance, one would still expect to
observe a correlation between measured vulnerabilities and insurance
holdings.
In practice, we find that aside from scale effects associated with
the level of income, the correlation between financial vulnerabilities
and life insurance holdings is essentially zero throughout the entire
life cycle. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that life
insurance bears little relation to needs at the time of purchase;
however, it tends to refute the hypothesis that households purchase
long-term contracts with initially appropriate insurance coverage but
fail to adjust this coverage through time as their circumstances change.
We also find that uninsured vulnerabilities are considerably
greater among younger couples than among older couples. Nearly
two-thirds of secondary earners between the ages of 22 and 39 have
significant uninsured financial vulnerabilities (projected reductions in
living standards exceeding 20%), and nearly one-third have severe
uninsured vulnerabilities (projected reductions exceeding 40%).
Moreover, for this age group, only one in five households with at-risk
secondary earners (those who would experience significant or severe
declines in living standard on the death of their spouse, ignoring
insurance) held sufficient life insurance to avert significant or severe
financial consequences. For the entire sample, in the absence of life
insurance, 56% of secondary earners and 6% of primary earners would have
experienced significant or severe declines in living standard on the
death of a spouse. Actual life insurance holdings reduce these figures
to, respectively, 42% and 5%. Thus, the overall impact of life insurance
holdings on financial vulnerabilities among at-risk households is
modest. Roughly two-thirds of poverty among surviving women and more
than one-third of poverty among surviving men resulted from a failure to
ensure survivors of an undiminished living standard through insurance.
Whereas our analysis of the correlation between vulnerabilities and
insurance holdings only requires us to assume that there is a reasonably
strong correlation between actual and measured vulnerabilities, our
findings concerning the prevalence of financial vulnerabilities rely
more heavily on the accuracy of computed vulnerabilities. In light of
the limitations of the SCF and the associated measurement problems, we
therefore examine the robustness of the findings summarized in the
preceding paragraphs with respect to a variety of alternative
assumptions and imputations.
Finally, we find evidence of a significant gender bias in life
insurance holdings. Specifically, for any given level of financial
vulnerabilities, couples provide significantly more protection for wives
than for husbands. For example, couples with severely at-risk wives on
average hold $166,628 of life insurance, whereas couples with severely
at-risk husbands on average hold only 15% of this amount ($24,827). Life
insurance reduced the average impact of a husband's death on the
living standard of a severely at-risk wife from a 65.5% decline to a
47.6% decline. In contrast, life insurance reduced the average impact of
a wife's death on the living standard of a severely at-risk husband
by a much smaller amount, from a 68.4% decline to a 64.1% decline. It is
unlikely that these results are attributable to measurement problems. If
anything, our analysis understates the true gender differential by
overstating the vulnerabilities of nonworking spouses relative to
working spouses. (1)
The article proceeds as follows. Section II discusses methods,
section III describes the data, section IV presents basic results,
section V provides sensitivity analysis, and section VI concludes.
II. A STRATEGY FOR MEASURING FINANCIAL VULNERABILITIES
Following Bernheim et al. (2003), we adopt a concrete and easily
understood yardstick for quantifying financial vulnerabilities: the
percentage decline in an individual's sustainable living standard
that would result from a spouse's death. (2) The use of this
yardstick permits us to make apples-to-apples comparisons of
vulnerabilities across households and investigate correlations between
vulnerabilities and insurance coverage. We also compare actual life
insurance holdings to a natural benchmark, defined as the level of
coverage required to ensure survivors of no change in their sustainable
living standard. It is worth emphasizing that we do not regard this
benchmark as a definitive standard of adequacy or rationality. Rational
decision makers may elect to purchase either higher or lower levels of
insurance. However, when combined with other evidence on household
objectives, comparisons with the benchmark potentially shed light on the
adequacy of life insurance coverage.
Concepts
We clarify our strategy for measuring financial vulnerabilities
through an example. Imagine that a husband and wife each live for at
most two years (equivalently, they are within two years of maximum life
span). Both are alive initially, but either may die before the second
year. The household's well-being depends on consumption in each
year and survival contingency. As will be discussed further, we allow
for the possibility that some ongoing expenditures are either exogenous or determined early in life by "sticky" choices. We refer to
these expenditures as fixed consumption and to residual spending as
"variable consumption." Let [y.sub.1] denote initial assets
plus first period earnings net of fixed consumption, and let [y.sub.2s]
denote second period earnings net of fixed consumption in state s = W,
H, B, where the state identifies survivors (wife, W, husband, H, or
both, B). The couple divides first-period resources between variable
consumption, [c.sub.1], saving, A, and insurance premiums,
[p.sub.i][L.sub.i], i = H, W, where [L.sub.i] represents the
second-period payment to i if his or her spouse dies, and [p.sub.i]
denotes the associated price per dollar of coverage. Assets A earn the
rate of return r. The couple faces the following constraints: [c.sub.1]
= [y.sub.1] - A - [p.sub.w][L.sub.w] - [p.sub.H][L.sub.H], [C.sub.2B] =
[y.sub.2B] + A (1 + r), and [c.sub.2i] = [y.sub.2i] + A(1 + r) +
[L.sub.i] for i = W, H, where [c.sub.2i] denotes second period variable
consumption in state i (for the moment, we ignore nonnegativity
restrictions on life insurance and assets). Defining
[p.sub.B][equivalent to][(1 + r).sup.-1] - [p.sub.w] - [p.sub.H], these
equations imply
(1) [c.sub.1] + [p.sub.B][c.sub.B] + [p.sub.W][c.sub.W] +
[p.sub.H][c.sub.H] = [y.sub.i] + [p.sub.B][c.sub.B] + [p.sub.W][c.sub.W]
+ [p.sub.H][c.sub.H] [equivalent to] Y.
We equate living standard with per capita variable consumption
adjusted for family composition. To determine each individual's
living standard when both are alive, we divide variable consumption by a
factor [2.sub.[alpha]]. We assume that 0 < [alpha] [less than or
equal to] 1; the second inequality reflects economies of scale
associated with shared living expenses. To maintain a living standard
that is constant across time and states of nature (in other words, one
that is undiminished if and when either spouse dies), the couple must
spend [2.sup.[alpha]]C dollars in every period and state where both are
alive for every C dollars in any state where only one survives. From
(1), it is apparent that the household's highest sustainable living
standard is
(2)[c.sup.*] = Y/([2.sup.[alpha]][[1 + [p.sub.B]] +
[[p.sub.W][c.sub.H]]).
The couple can guarantee that spouse j's death will not
diminish i's living standard from its highest sustainable level,
[c.sup.*], by purchasing a life insurance policy with face value
[L.sup.*.sub.i] = ([c.sup.*] - [y.sub.2i]) + ([y.sub.2B] -
[2.sup.[alpha]][c.sup.*]). (3)
We measure underlying financial vulnerabilities by comparing an
individual's highest sustainable living standard, [c.sup.*], with
[c.sup.n.sub.i] [equivalent to] [y.sub.2i] + A(1 + r), which represents
the living standard he or she would enjoy if widowed, ignoring life
insurance. We define the variable IMPACT (ignoring insurance) as
([c.sup.n.sub.i] /[[c.sup.*]] - 1) x 100, i = W, H. This is a measure of
the percent by which the survivor's living standard would (with no
insurance protection) fall short of or exceed the couple's highest
sustainable living standard. Similarly, we measure uninsured financial
vulnerabilities by comparing [c.sup.*] with [c.sup.a.sub.i] [equivalent
to] [y.sub.2i] + A(1 + r) + [L.sup.a.sub.i], which represents the living
standard that the individual would actually enjoy if widowed, based on
actual life insurance coverage, [L.sup.a.sub.i]. We define the variable
IMPACT(actual) as ([[c.sup.a.sub.i]/[c.sup.*]] - 1) x 100. This is a
measure of the percent by which the survivor's living standard
would (given actual levels of coverage) fall short of or exceed the
couple's highest sustainable living standard. The IMPACT variables
are based on a concrete and easily understood yardstick for quantifying
the consequences of a spouse's death. (4) We also compare actual
household life insurance holdings, [L.sup.a.sub.H] + [L.sup.a.sub.W],
with the benchmark level, [L.sup.*.sub.H] + [L.sup.*.sub.W]
For the preceding example, we implicitly assumed that individuals
could borrow at the rate r and issue survival-contingent claims at the
prices [p.sub.H] and [p.sub.W]. As a practical matter, households
encounter liquidity constraints. They are also typically unable or at
least very reluctant to purchase negative quantities of life insurance
(buy annuities). (5) In solving for each household's highest
sustainable living standard, we take these restrictions into account,
smoothing consumption to the greatest extent possible. (6)
When the life insurance constraint binds, the benchmark living
standard for a survivor, [c.sup.*.sub.i] (where i = H or W), may be
greater than the benchmark living standard for the couple while both
spouses are still alive, [c.sup.*.sub.B]. This observation raises the
following practical issue: When calculating IMPACT, should we set
[c.sup.*] = [c.sup.*.sub.i], or [c.sup.*] = [c.sup.*.sub.B]? Were we to
use [c.sup.*.sub.B] actual IMPACT would be positive not only for
households that depart from the benchmark by purchasing additional
insurance ([L.sup.a.sub.i] > [L.sup.*.sub.i]) but also for
constrained households that conform to the benchmark by purchasing no
insurance ([L.sup.a.sub.i] = [L.sup.*.sub.i] = 0). In contrast, the use
of [c.sup.*.sub.i] implies that actual IMPACT is positive when
[L.sup.a.sub.i] > [L.sup.*.sub.i] and zero when [L.sup.a.sub.i] =
[L.sup.*.sub.i] = 0. Because we wish to use actual IMPACT as a measure
of the extent to which a household deviates from the
consumption-smoothed benchmark, we select [c.sup.*.sub.i] rather than
[c.sup.*.sub.B]. As a result, the value of IMPACT ignoring insurance is
always non-positive (even though, absent insurance, the survivor's
material living standard might actually increase on his or her
spouse's death), and it equals zero whenever the corresponding
benchmark insurance level, [L.sup.*.sub.i], is zero.
Implementation
We actually evaluate each household's financial
vulnerabilities using a more elaborate and realistic life-cycle model.
As mentioned previously, the model is embedded in a financial planning software program, Economic Security Planner (ESPlanner). Although a
complete description of the model would be prohibitively lengthy, it is
important to summarize some key features.
For our base-case calculations, we assume that each individual
lives to a maximum age of 95. We include children as members of the
household through age 18. We represent household scale economies as
follows: an expenditure of [(N + [beta]K)[alpha]]C, when there are N
adults and K children in the household provides the same standard of
living for each household member as does an expenditure of C when there
is only one adult in the household (this generalizes the adjustment
factor used in our simple illustration). The coefficient [beta] is a
child adult equivalency factor; we set it equal to 0.5. (7) The exponent a captures economies of scale in shared living. We set it equal to
0.678, which implies that a two-adult household must spend 1.6 times as
much as a one-adult household to achieve the same living standard. (8)
Insurance needs depend on differences in survival-contingent income
streams. Consequently, a careful and thorough treatment of the Social
Security system is essential. In calculating benefits for retirement,
survivors, parents, children, spouses, and dependent children, the model
accounts for eligibility rules, early retirement reductions, delayed
retirement credits, benefit recomputation, the legislated phased
increase in the normal retirement age, the earnings test, restrictions
on maximum family benefits; the wage indexation of average indexed
monthly earnings, and the price indexation of benefits once received.
Various characteristics of the tax system, such as rate structure
and the treatment of married couples, can alter insurance needs by
influencing the distribution of after-tax income across the various
survival contingencies. Consequently, a careful treatment of taxation is
also critical. The model calculates federal and state income and payroll
taxes for each year in each survival contingency. (9) It incorporates a
wide range of provisions, including federal deductions and exemptions,
the decision to itemize deductions, the taxation of Social Security
benefits, the earned income tax credit, the child tax credit, the
phase-out at higher income levels of itemized deductions, and the
indexation of tax brackets to the consumer price index. In computing federal deductions, it determines whether the sum of state income taxes,
mortgage interest payments, and property taxes is large enough to
justify itemization. Contributions to tax-favored retirement savings
accounts are excluded from taxable income, and withdrawals are included.
Though the model determines total saving simultaneously with life
insurance, tax-favored saving is specified exogenously.
Choices concerning housing may also affect life insurance needs.
Unlike many other expenditures, housing outlays are not easily smoothed.
It is difficult to scale mortgage, property tax, and insurance payments
up and down with other expenditures. Cost and inconvenience discourage
many households from moving or refinancing mortgages; others form
psychological attachments to their homes and resist changing residences
prior to death (Venti and Wise, 2001). Moreover, few households access
the equity in their homes through refinancing or reverse annuity mortgages (Caplin, 2001). Consequently, for our base-case calculations
we treat housing as fixed consumption. In effect, we assume that couples
and survivors remain in the same home until death and die with home
equity intact. Formally, we subtract housing expenses from income off
the top, itemizing mortgage interest and property taxes as deductions
for federal income tax purposes when it is optimal to do so, prior to
smoothing variable consumption.
Several potentially important factors are omitted from our
analysis. We do not model uncertainty concerning future income and
nondiscretionary expenses (e.g., medical care). Because small groups of
individuals can share risks to some extent, the adverse effect of
uncertainty on living standard is probably greater for widows and
widowers than for couples. For this reason, our analysis tends to
understate insurance needs. We also neglect the possibility that an
individual might remarry after a spouse's death. The extent to
which remarriage mitigates the financial consequences of a spouse's
death depends on one's view of the marriage market (see Lundberg,
1999, for a discussion). Although relatively few elderly individuals
remarry after the death of a spouse (see Bernheim et al., 2003),
remarriage is more common among younger households.
Table 1 summarizes some illustrative life insurance calculations.
(10) We begin with a couple consisting of a 40-year-old man earning
$45,000 per year and a 38-year-old woman earning $25,000 per year. The
man intends to retire at age 64, the woman at age 63. They have two
children, ages 5 and 7. The net value of their nonhousing assets is
$50,000; in addition, they own a $150,000 home and have an unpaid
mortgage balance of $120,000. They expect their real earnings to grow at
the rate of 1% per year until retirement. They also expect to earn a
real after-tax return of 3% on their non-housing investments. According
to our model, this couple must purchase $285,922 in term insurance on
the husband's life, and no insurance on the wife's life, to
ensure each potential survivor of an undiminished living standard. The
remainder of the table illustrates the sensitivity of insurance needs to
changes in various household characteristics and economic parameters. As
one would expect, benchmark life insurance falls with age and with the
earnings of the insured spouse; it rises with the addition of a child,
with an increase in the rate of earnings growth, and with a reduction in
the real interest rate (these last two changes increase the present
discounted value of future human capital). There is one surprising
finding: benchmark insurance also rises with the removal of one child.
This result is attributable to the associated changes in Social Security
survivor benefits, which are quantitatively important for the
hypothesized family. For an otherwise identical family with high income
(for which Social Security survivor benefits are less important),
benchmark insurance rises monotonically with the number of children.
Interpretation
We do not regard any single measure of financial vulnerability as
ideal. Though elaborate, the life-cycle model used in our analysis is
still an abstraction, and we have imperfect information concerning the
economic circumstances of each household (see the appendix). Nor do we
regard the benchmark level of life insurance as an objective standard of
adequacy or rationality. Optimal insurance coverage depends on a variety
of considerations, including (but not limited to) the manner in which
marginal utilities vary across survival states, the weights that
households attach to the well-being of each family member, degrees of
risk aversion, and load factors (more generally, the degree to which the
industry departs from actuarially fair pricing). Consequently, it is
possible to rationalize a wide range of behaviors.
Nevertheless, the absence of a significant correlation between life
insurance and financial vulnerabilities (measured by benchmark life
insurance) would be difficult to reconcile with theories of rational
financial behavior. Even if a household places less weight on the
well-being of a particular spouse, and even if it must pay actuarially
unfair rates, it should still obtain greater insurance protection when
the spouse in question is exposed to more severe financial consequences.
To explain the absence of a correlation, one would need to believe
either that our measure of benchmark life insurance is largely unrelated
to underlying vulnerabilities, or that marginal utilities vary in a way
that just offsets the differences in measured vulnerabilities. Both
possibilities strike us as improbable.
Evidence of widespread and substantial uninsured vulnerabilities
(as measured by actual IMPACT or by the divergence of actual insurance
from the benchmark) are also more difficult to rationalize than it might
at first appear. Most potential explanations presuppose that households
deliberately choose different living standards for survivors. Yet this
premise is inconsistent with preliminary findings from a financial
planning case study at Boston University involving nearly 500 subjects.
Each of these individuals constructed a comprehensive financial plan
using the same financial planning software employed in the current
study. Participants hoped to benefit from these sessions and therefore
had strong incentives to provide accurate information. Though the
software permits users to specify different living standards for intact
couples and each potential survivor, the vast majority of subjects
selected the same living standard for each contingency. (11) Though it
is perfectly rational for individuals to have other objectives, it is
irrational for individuals with these objectives to purchase coverage
that diverges significantly from our benchmark (assuming, of course,
that the benchmark is derived from a model that correctly depicts all
important aspects of the household's opportunity set).
III. DATA
The 1995 wave of the SCF was fielded between June and December
1995. It surveyed over 4,000 households (2,874 married couples, 1,425
single individuals), with oversampling of the wealthy. The data cover
demographics, income, wealth, debt and credit, pensions, attitudes about
financial matters, the nature of various transactions with various types
of financial institutions, housing, real estate, businesses, vehicles,
health and life insurance, current and past employment, current Social
Security benefits, inheritances, charitable contributions, education,
and retirement plans. The architects of the SCF data files imputed missing information, supplying five "implicates' for each
household. (12) We use the first implicate.
Our final sample consists of 1,033 couples. We excluded couples for
the following reasons: (1) a spouse was self-employed or owned and
actively managed a business (67% of excluded observations); (2) a spouse
was temporarily unemployed (11%); (3) neither spouse had regular
earnings as an employee (54%); (4) labor earnings were defined in terms
of a unit other than time worked, for example by the piece (0.7%); (5)
mortgage information was inconsistent (7.4%); (6) property taxes were
greater than 5% of the value of the home (2.6%); (7) a spouse was over
the age of 85 (1.6%); or (8) the couple's reported income and other
economic resources were insufficient to support its reported fixed
expenditures (3.3%) (note that some households fell into more than one
category).
Accurate measurement of life insurance coverage is, of course,
particularly critical for our analysis. Fortunately, the SCF data match
up reasonably well with other sources of information concerning this
variable. In Table 2, we make some comparisons between statistics on
life insurance coverage (including all individual and group policies)
drawn from the SCF and from a survey fielded by the Life Insurance
Marketing Research Organization, an authoritative industry source.
Generally, the figures are quite close. Certainly, there is no
indication that the SCF understates life insurance coverage. It is, of
course, possible that households underreported certain forms of
insurance (e.g., employer-provided policies) in both surveys. As an
additional check on the validity of the data, we computed the aggregate
amount of in-force life insurance implied by the SCF survey responses
and compared this with total in-force life insurance reported by the
industry (obtained from the American Council on Life Insurance, 1999).
Because the latter figure is derived directly from company records, it
is presumably reliable. The SCF survey data accounts for roughly 81% of
aggregate in-force life insurance ($9.52 trillion out of $11.70
trillion). Because some life insurance policies are owned by companies,
trusts, and foreign individuals rather than by U.S. households, the SCF
figure appears to be in the right ballpark.
An important limitation of the SCF is that it contains information
only on the total amount of life insurance held by each household, and
not on the division of this insurance between spouses. In contrast to
Bernheim et al. (2003) (who treated an individual spouse as the unit of
analysis throughout), we therefore focus in much of our analysis on
household aggregates. However, for some purposes, we also impute the
fraction of insurance held to protect each spouse. The imputation is
based on a regression equation explaining the fraction of a
couple's total life insurance held on the life of the husband as a
function of the age of each spouse, the husband's earnings, the
husband's share of the couple's total nonasset income, family
size, and the husband's share of the couple's total benchmark
life insurance, estimated using data from the 1992 HRS.
IV. RESULTS
Analysis of Household Insurance Holdings
We begin with an analysis of household insurance holdings. For the
results in this section, it is not necessary to impute the fraction of a
household's insurance held to protect each spouse.
Table 3 provides a variety of summary statistics, including some
simple information on insurance coverage. According to figures in panel
A, the average benchmark level of life insurance for a household
exceeded actual life insurance holdings by a wide margin (more than two
to one for the mean, and nearly three to one for the median). One might
be inclined to conclude that on average, life insurance addresses
between one-third to one-half of underlying exposures. However, this
conclusion is premature. Underlying financial exposures vary
dramatically across households. From an inspection of averages (Table
3), one cannot determine whether the distribution of insurance holdings
matches up with the distribution of exposures. As we will see, the
averages mask a startling mismatch between vulnerabilities and insurance
holdings.
Table 4 provides a first glimpse at the relation between benchmark
insurance and actual insurance across households. In panel A, we group
households into four categories based on the benchmark insurance level
(aggregated over spouses). As indicated in the second column, similar
fractions of the data sample fall into each of these groups. The figures
in the third column suggest that there is practically no relationship
between benchmark insurance and the likelihood of holding some
insurance. In this sense, the decision to obtain insurance appears to be
uncorrelated with underlying vulnerabilities. The fourth and fifth
columns permit comparisons between the medians of benchmark insurance
and actual insurance (in each case, household aggregates) for each of
the four groups. There is perhaps a small correlation across groups
between insurance purchases and the benchmark. A similar conclusion
follows from a comparison of means (columns six and seven), though the
average level of actual insurance for those with no underlying
vulnerabilities (benchmark insurance of zero) is anomalously large.
Though there is some indication that benchmark insurance is mildly
correlated with actual insurance, the proper interpretation of this
correlation is unclear. From panel A of Table 4, it is apparent that
differences in the median and mean levels of actual insurance across
groups correspond reasonably closely to differences in median household
income (second to last column). Consider the alternative hypothesis that
households with more income mechanically acquire more insurance without
much deliberate consideration of vulnerabilities and needs. It is
reasonable to entertain this possibility because many employers
automatically provide life insurance equal to some multiple of salary,
and because life insurance agents frequently base recommendations on
simple rules of thumb involving multiples of earnings. This hypothesis
would account for the positive correlation between benchmark and actual
insurance levels among those for whom the benchmark is positive.
Moreover, it would explain the otherwise anomalously high levels of
insurance holdings among those for who benchmark insurance is zero (and
who also tend to have higher incomes).
Panel B of Table 4 contains the same information as panel A, except
that insurance holdings (again, household aggregates) are expressed as
ratios to household earnings. This serves as a rough control for
earnings, and permits us to evaluate the extent of the relationship
between benchmark and actual levels of insurance that exists
independently of the mechanical "income effect" hypothesized
in the preceding paragraph. Once again, we divide the sample into four
groups of roughly equal sizes (as indicated in the second column).
Though the percent insured rises slightly with the ratio of benchmark
insurance to earnings across the first three groups, it is lowest for
the most vulnerable group (those with ratios of benchmark insurance to
earnings in excess of 8). Moreover, regardless of whether one looks at
medians (columns four and five) or means (columns six and seven), the
correlation across groups between the ratio of benchmark insurance to
earnings and the ratio of actual insurance to earnings is weak at best.
These observations suggests that the small correlation between benchmark
and actual insurance levels noted in our discussion of panel A results
from an income effect and not from deliberate evaluation of other
factors affecting vulnerabilities.
Table 5 summarizes the relationship between benchmark and actual
levels of life insurance (household aggregates) through some simple
univariate regression models. Panel A presents results based on levels
of life insurance, and panel B examines ratios of life insurance to
earnings. In each panel, we estimate the equation of interest using
three different methods: Ordinary least squares (OLS), tobit (to check
for potential biases arising from the sizable fraction of households who
hold no insurance), and median regression (to check for sensitivity to
outliers). In addition, we also estimate a probit model explaining the
likelihood that a household's actual insurance holdings are
strictly positive.
In panel A, we find that a $1 increase in the benchmark tends to
coincide with a 22-cent increase in actual insurance holdings for the
household. For each of the three methods employed, we estimate this
coefficient with considerable precision. Households with higher levels
of benchmark insurance are also more likely to hold strictly positive
insurance, but the difference is not statistically significant. In panel
B we find that the correlations noted in panel A result almost entirely
from systematic differences in income. The ratio of benchmark insurance
to earnings is almost completely unrelated to the ratio of actual
insurance to earnings and is in fact negatively related to the
likelihood of holding insurance.
The logic of examining simple univariate regressions is that
benchmark insurance functions as a sufficient statistic for the full
range of factors--ages of spouses, number of children, division of
earnings between spouses, and so forth--that determine underlying
vulnerabilities. Certainly, it would not be sensible to control for all
of the factors affecting vulnerabilities, because this would leave no
residual variation in benchmark insurance from which to identify the
covariation with actual insurance.
There are, however, valid reasons to investigate the correlation
between benchmark and actual levels of insurance conditional on a subset of the factors that determine vulnerabilities. As mentioned at the
outset, Bernheim et al. (2003) previously documented the absence of a
correlation between insurance holdings and vulnerabilities among older
workers. One of our primary objectives is to distinguish between two
alternative explanations for this pattern: that insurance purchases are
largely uncorrelated with vulnerabilities, or that households purchase
long-term policies based on vulnerabilities relatively early in life but
subsequently fail to adjust coverage appropriately because of inertia or
other psychological considerations. To accomplish this objective, we
must study the relationship between life insurance and underlying
vulnerabilities conditional on age.
The final column of panels A and B in Table 4 provide a separate
reason to control for age. Note that both the absolute value of
benchmark insurance and the ratio of the benchmark to household earnings
decline sharply with the couple's average age (defined as the
average of the husband's and wife's ages). This stands to
reason, because younger individuals generally have more future human
capital to protect. Now consider the following two-part hypothesis: (1)
Young individuals tend to procrastinate with respect to decisions
concerning life insurance, and (2) when they finally obtain insurance,
the amount purchased is closely related to vulnerabilities. Because
younger households have greater vulnerabilities, the first portion of
the hypothesis would tend to create a negative correlation between
insurance holdings and underlying vulnerabilities. In principle, this
could obscure the positive correlation implied by the second portion of
the hypothesis.
Table 6 contains various regressions in which we control for the
effects of age. In each case, the dependent variable is the ratio of
actual life insurance (household aggregate) to household earnings. (13)
There are two separate sets of results. For the first four regressions,
we include linear and quadratic terms in the couple's average age
(already defined), as well as an interaction term between age and the
ratio of benchmark life insurance (household aggregate) to household
earnings. The interaction term permits us to investigate the hypothesis
that the correlation between insurance holdings and vulnerabilities
changes with age. If households initially purchase appropriate levels of
insurance but subsequently fail to adjust their holdings as
circumstances change, we would expect to obtain a positive coefficient
for the benchmark insurance term and a negative coefficient for the
interaction term. For the last four regressions in Table 6, we adopt a
more flexible functional specification. In particular, we divide the
population into five age groups and control both for age-group dummies
and for interactions between these dummies and the benchmark
insurance--to-earnings ratio. This is equivalent to estimating a
separate univariate regression for each age group. At the bottom of the
table, we report test statistics for two hypotheses. The first is that
there is no relation between actual insurance and benchmark insurance at
any age. The second is that the relation between actual insurance and
benchmark insurance does not change systematically with age.
In the first three specifications of Table 6, the coefficient of
the benchmark insurance-to-earnings ratio is small, slightly negative,
and statistically insignificant, whereas the insurance-age interaction
term is indistinguishable from zero. This implies that there is
essentially no relationship between actual insurance and benchmark
insurance at any age. The test statistics at the bottom of the table
confirm this impression. For the fourth specification (a probit model),
the coefficient of the benchmark insurance-to-earnings ratio is negative
and marginally significant, and the coefficient of the interaction term
is positive but insignificant. One rejects the hypothesis that
vulnerabilities (as measured by benchmark insurance) have no effect on
the likelihood of holding insurance at any age, but the direction of the
effect is counterintuitive: The probit coefficients imply that the
likelihood of holding insurance is negatively correlated with benchmark
insurance for households under 100 years of age.
Regression results based on a more flexible functional
specification tell a similar story. The age-specific benchmark insurance
coefficients are generally small, frequently negative, and almost always
insignificant. For the OLS and tobit specifications, one cannot reject
the joint hypothesis that there is no significant correlation between
benchmark insurance and actual insurance at any age. In every
specification, we fail to reject the hypothesis that this correlation
does not vary significantly with age.
Analysis of Vulnerabilities for Individual Spouses
We turn next to an individual-specific analysis of financial
vulnerabilities. This requires us to impute the fraction of a
household's insurance held to protect each spouse, as described in
section III.
It is useful to begin once again with summary statistics. Panel B
of Table 3 indicates that the average level of insurance actually held
on the lives of husbands and primary earners diverged sharply from the
average benchmark, whereas the average level of insurance actually held
on the lives of wives and secondary earners was quite close to the
average benchmark. This implies that on average, wives and secondary
earners faced substantial uninsured vulnerabilities, whereas husbands
and primary earners did not.
In the second-to-last line of panel B ([DELTA] liv. std., ignore
ins.), we tabulate means and medians for IMPACT calculated as if each
household held no life insurance. This variable measures underlying
financial exposure. Without insurance, the average living standards for
surviving husbands, wives, primary earners, and secondary earners would
have been, respectively, 5.7%, 28.6%, 3.8%, and 30.5% below their
benchmark levels. Because the corresponding medians for husbands and
primary earners are zero, we can infer that more than half of these
individuals were not at risk of a reduction in sustainable living
standard. Likewise, because the corresponding median living standard
reductions for wives and secondary earners were 21.5% and 24.6%,
respectively, we conclude that more than half of these individuals
confronted significant underlying vulnerabilities.
In the final line of panel B ([DELTA] liv. std., imputed), we
tabulate means and medians for IMPACT based on imputed insurance
holdings. This variable measures uninsured financial exposure. Life
insurance reduced the mean value of IMPACT by roughly 40% for wives and
secondary earners. The decline in the median value of IMPACT for
secondary earners is a bit larger, whereas the proportional decline in
median IMPACT for wives is closer to two-thirds. For husbands and
primary earners, life insurance had a relatively minor absolute effect
on mean and median IMPACT, but the average underlying vulnerabilities
were small for these groups to begin with.
As before, the averages in Table 3 obscure the mismatch between
vulnerabilities and insurance holdings. Table 7 provides further
information on the distributions of the IMPACT variables. As discussed
previously, ignoring insurance, IMPACT is never strictly greater than
zero. This reflects the fact that we have imposed a nonnegativity
constraint on life insurance purchases. An individual's living
standard may rise on a spouse's death; however, without life
insurance, it cannot exceed the living standard that the he or she would
enjoy as a survivor assuming implementation of the (constrained)
benchmark financial plan. Note also that actual IMPACT is exactly equal
to zero for a substantial fraction of the population. Generally, these
are individuals for whom actual and (model-generated) benchmark levels
of insurance protection are both zero.
From Table 7, it is again evident that insurance holdings match up
rather poorly with financial vulnerabilities. Overall, 36.8% of wives,
64.1% of husbands, 32.0% of secondary earners, and 68.8% of primary
earners had strictly positive life insurance protection despite the fact
that they would have experienced increases in living standards on the
deaths of their spouses (in Table 7, those with actual IMPACT greater
than zero). Insurance reduced the fraction of individuals at risk for
severe financial consequences (defined as a decline in living standard
of 40% or greater) from 31.0% to 19.3% for wives, from 32.5% to 20.6%
for secondary earners, from 3.5% to 2.9% for husbands, and from 1.9% to
1.6% for primary earners. Similarly, insurance reduced the fraction of
individuals at risk for significant financial consequences (defined as a
decline in living standard of 20% or greater) from 51.9% to 37.9% for
wives, from 55.9% to 41.7% for secondary earners, from 10.0% to 8.5% for
husbands, and from 6.0% to 4.7% for primary earners. Roughly speaking,
only 15% to 25% of households with significant financial exposures held
sufficient life insurance to avert significant consequences for
survivors.
Table 8 provides further information on the extent to which
insurance mitigates financial vulnerabilities. We subdivide the
population based on underlying financial exposure, measured by the value
of IMPACT, ignoring insurance. For each subgroup, we then calculate the
means of both IMPACT variables, as well as the percentage of households
holding no life insurance, and averages for benchmark and actual
insurance.
We draw three conclusions from Table 8. First, life insurance had,
at best, a moderate impact on financial exposures among the at-risk
population. For example, among severely at-risk wives, insurance reduced
the average consequences of a spouse's death (mean IMPACT) by only
27% (17.9 percentage points), from -65.5% to -47.6%. This is a far cry
from the one-half overall reduction in mean IMPACT for wives noted in
Table 3. For this same group, households would have needed to hold an
average of $630,079 in total life insurance to ensure both the husband
and wife of an undiminished living standard. In fact, on average, they
held only one-quarter of this amount ($166,628). This implies an even
larger discrepancy (more than $460,000) than the overall difference
(just under $240,000) noted in Table 3.
Second, for a fixed level of financial exposure, households were
more inclined to protect women than men. For example, among severely
at-risk husbands, insurance reduced the average consequences of the
wife's death (mean IMPACT) by only 6% (4.3 percentage points), from
-68.4% to -64.1%. This contrasts sharply with the corresponding figures
for wives, already noted. One might question the reliability of this
finding on the grounds that we have imputed the division of insurance
between spouses based on patterns in the HRS. However, the gender
difference is plainly not an artifact of the imputation procedure. For
example, couples with severely at-risk wives on average held in total
$190,388 of life insurance (versus $166,628 imputed to the protection of
the wife), whereas couples with severely at-risk husbands on average
held in total only one-third of this amount ($62,689 versus $24,827
imputed to the protection of the husband).
Third, the likelihood of holding insurance bears little if any
relation to underlying vulnerabilities, as measured by IMPACT (ignoring
insurance). Indeed, the fraction of couples without life insurance is
generally largest for those with severe financial exposures (IMPACT
ignoring insurance less than -40%).
Thus far we have measured the consequences of a spouse's death
in terms of the proportional change in sustainable living standard. For
many individuals, the potential financial consequences of a
spouse's death are also severe in absolute terms. With maximal consumption smoothing (benchmark insurance), sustainable consumption for
3.58% of surviving wives and 2.61% of surviving husbands would fall
below the 1995 poverty thresholds published by the U.S. Census Bureau.
Taking into account actual levels of insurance coverage, poverty rates
would have been 10.45% among surviving wives and 4.16% among surviving
husbands. These findings imply that 66% (6.87 of 10.45 percentage
points) of poverty among surviving women and 37% (1.55 out of 4.16
percentage points) of poverty among surviving men resulted from a
failure to ensure survivors of an undiminished living standard through
insurance. Ignoring insurance, poverty rates would have been 13.17%
among surviving wives and 4.26% among surviving husbands. Consequently,
insurance eliminated only 28% of the avoidable poverty among surviving
widows (2.72 out of 9.59 percentage points) and only 6% of the avoidable
poverty among surviving men (0.1 out of 1.63 percentage points).
Results for Population Subgroups
Table 9 provides disaggregated results. For various population
subgroups, we report the ratio of actual-to-benchmark life insurance
calculated two ways (mean to mean and median to median). These figures
pertain to the entire household and therefore do not rely on the imputed
division of insurance between spouses. For primary and secondary
earners, we also report the percentage of each subgroup with severe and
significant exposures based on IMPACT with actual insurance
("frequency"), as well as the fractional reduction in these
exposures resulting from actual insurance holdings ("fraction
addressed"), (14) in each instance using the imputed division of
insurance (results for husbands and wives, not reported in the table,
are similar).
Uninsured financial vulnerabilities were more common among
low-income households, couples with disparate earnings, relatively young
households, couples with dependent children, and nonwhites. Thus,
factors that are highly correlated with underlying vulnerabilities
(particularly earnings disparities, age, and children) are also highly
correlated with uninsured vulnerabilities. This finding is, of course,
implied by the poor correlation between vulnerabilities and insurance
holdings.
According to Table 9, conditional on the existence of a significant
or severe vulnerability, households with lower incomes, greater income
disparities between spouses, no children, and nonwhites are less likely
to moderate the financial consequences of a spouse's death through
life insurance (see the column labeled Fraction Addressed). The
relationship between age and the conditional likelihood of addressing a
significant or severe vulnerability was hump-shaped, with a peak in the
40-55-year age range. Households were generally less likely to address
vulnerabilities for primary earners. Note that a low proclivity to
address exposures can coincide either with high (as in the case of
lower-income households) or low (as in the case of older individuals and
primary earners) levels of underlying vulnerability.
When one compares households of similar ages, our results are quite
close to those derived from the HRS data in Bernheim et al. (2003). (15)
For example, we find that 13.4% of secondary earners between the ages of
56 and 70 have significant uninsured vulnerabilities, whereas 7.6% have
severe uninsured vulnerabilities; the comparable figures in Bernheim et
al. (2003) for 60- to 69-year-old survivors are 14.1% and 8.9%.
Moreover, the data exhibit the same qualitative patterns with respect to
the magnitudes of vulnerabilities, as well as with respect to the
propensity to address vulnerabilities, across household categories.
It is important to reiterate that data limitations precluded
previous studies from shedding light on the insurance holdings of
younger households. Consequently, our findings concerning age are
particularly noteworthy. According to Table 9, for 22- to 39-year-olds,
household life insurance holdings averaged only 27.6% of the benchmark,
compared with 82.5% for 40- to 55-year-olds. Nearly two-thirds of
secondary earners between the ages of 22 and 39 have significant
financial vulnerabilities (projected reductions in living standards
exceeding 20%), and nearly one-third have severe vulnerabilities
(projected reductions exceeding 40%). Moreover, for this age group, only
one in five households with at-risk secondary earners (those who would
experience significant or severe declines in living standard on the
death of their spouse, ignoring insurance) held sufficient life
insurance to avert significant or severe financial consequences.
V. ROBUSTNESS
Given the limitations of the SCF data, it is important to examine
the extent to which measured vulnerabilities are sensitive to changes in
key assumptions and parameters. We summarize a variety of alternative
calculations in Table 10. As in Table 9, we report household-level
ratios of actual to benchmark life insurance, as well as the fractions
of primary and secondary earners with severe and significant uninsured
exposures. For purposes of comparison, we reproduce our base-case
results in the first line of the table.
Changes in the real interest rate, baseline wage growth rate, and
maximum lifespan have relatively little effect on the fractions of
spouses with severe and significant vulnerabilities. (16) In each case,
this reflects the opposing effects of offsetting forces. With higher
interest rates, a given level of life insurance coverage generates
higher real income. However, because survivors are typically more
dependent on long-duration life annuities than intact couples, the
present discounted value of their resources tends to decline by a larger
proportion when the rate of return rises. For older workers, the rate of
wage growth is relatively unimportant because it affects comparatively
few years of earnings. Moreover, although a given rate of growth
produces a larger absolute increase in earnings for primary earners,
secondary earners tend to be younger and therefore benefit from higher
growth over a longer time-frame. A reduction in maximum lifespan reduces
the resources that a survivor needs to achieve a given living standard
but increases the living standard that the intact couple can achieve
from available resources.
The consumption growth rate refers to steepness of the sustainable
living standard trajectory. For our base case, we compute the highest
living standard that is sustainable throughout life in all
contingencies; this corresponds to a consumption growth rate of zero.
For sufficiently patient (impatient) households, it may be more natural
to construct benchmarks based on a rising (falling) living standard
trajectory. The proportional effects of a change in the consumption
growth rate on the resource needs of survivors and intact couples are
approximately equal. Our results are therefore robust with respect to
changes in this parameter.
The frequencies of exposure to significant and severe financial
consequences are noticeably lower in the absence of household scale
economies (an extreme and somewhat implausible assumption). It is
somewhat higher when we reduce the rate of pension survivor benefits
from 100% to 50%, but the change is much smaller than that reported in
Bernheim et al. (2003). The discrepancy is presumably attributable to
differences between the age distributions of the SCF and HRS samples.
For younger households, pension survivor benefits make less of a
difference both because they are further in the future and thus more
heavily discounted and because younger workers have not yet accumulated substantial pension entitlements.
As mentioned previously, our base-case assumptions concerning
housing are consistent with empirical evidence indicating that
individuals avoid changing residences (increasingly so as they age) and
that they resist using housing equity to finance ordinary living
expenses. However, because some widows do move, we examine sensitivity
to two alternative assumptions. For the first, we adopt the extreme
position that housing consumption is completely and continuously
flexible and that housing equity is a perfect substitute for other forms
of wealth. For the second alternative, we adopt an intermediate
position: A survivor downsizes the couple's primary residence by
30%, but thereafter avoids using housing equity to finance ordinary
living expenses. (17) Though the first alternative dramatically reduces
the estimated frequencies of individuals at risk of severe or
significant financial consequences, the effect of the second (and, we
think, more plausible) alternative is relatively small.
As in Bernheim et al. (2003), our base-case calculations assume
that survivors do not alter their labor force participation. Because
nonworking wives approaching retirement age have limited employment
options subsequent to their husbands' deaths, this assumption was
appropriate for the HRS sample. It is somewhat more problematic for the
younger households included in the SCF. Conceivably, some couples may
hold apparently low levels of insurance on a primary earner because, in
the event of his or her death, they expect the surviving spouse to find
full-time employment. We note, however, that this explanation is
inconsistent with a finding reported in section IV: Fixing the level of
underlying vulnerability, couples are less likely to obtain insurance
for the protection of primary earners (and husbands) than for secondary
earners (and wives). Because primary earners are already (in most cases)
fully employed, secondary earners have greater latitude to increase
labor force participation. Consequently, for a given level of
vulnerability, one would expect to observe greater protection of primary
earners, which is not the case.
To evaluate the sensitivity of our results with respect to possible
changes in labor force participation, we consider an extreme alternative
assumption: All survivors, whether out of the labor force or employed
part-time, shift to full-time employment. We impute full-time earnings
based on regressions of earnings on demographic characteristics,
estimated separately for fully employed men and women. A survivor's
contingent earnings are set equal to the maximum of imputed earnings and
actual earnings. Due to familiar sample selection problems, this
procedure tends to overstate potential earnings for nonworkers; it
therefore understates survivors' financial vulnerabilities. As
indicated in Table 10, the estimated frequencies of financial
vulnerability are reasonably sensitive to this alternative assumption.
This contrasts with the findings of Bernheim et al. (2003). The
difference is not particularly surprising, because the ability to alter
labor supply is more important for younger workers. Note, however, that
substantial uninsured vulnerabilities are reasonably widespread even
with this extreme alternative assumption. This, too, is not surprising,
given the high levels of vulnerabilities among dual-earner households
noted in Table 9.
Not surprisingly, this alternative assumption concerning
conditional changes in labor force participation has a larger impact on
measured vulnerabilities among younger households. It does not, however,
reverse the qualitative conclusions that uninsured vulnerabilities
decline with age, or that substantial uninsured vulnerabilities are
widespread among young households. In particular, the ratio of means for
actual to benchmark household insurance is 0.314 for 22- to 39 year
olds, 0.975 for 40- to 55-year-olds, 2.76 for 56- to 70-year-olds, and
16.8 for those over 70; the corresponding ratio of medians is 0.235 for
22- to 39-year-olds, 1.45 for 40- to 55-year-olds, and not defined for
older households (because the median benchmark is zero). Moreover, the
fraction of secondary earners with severe (significant) vulnerabilities
is 15.5% (42.9%) for 22- to 39-year-olds, 7.7% (19.6%) for 40- to
55-year-olds, 5.1% (12.1%) for 56- to 70-year-olds, and 8.8% (11.8%) for
those over 70.
In principle, shifts in nonlabor income might also cushion the
financial impact of a spouse's death. Our analysis makes no
allowance for this possibility. Presumably, the most important source of
potential support is assistance from relatives. Bernheim et al. (2003)
report that between the first two waves of the HRS, only 6.2% of new
widows received any assistance of this type. Between the second and
third waves, the figure was 7.5%; and between the third and fourth
waves, it was only 2.5%. In addition, support may have been modest or
temporary in many of these cases. Consequently, there is little evidence
that external support payments are significant in practice. Although the
HRS only provides information on older widows, we conjecture that these
figures are lower for young widows (except perhaps where young children
are present).
As emphasized in section III, the SCF collects information only on
total life insurance for each household and not on the proportions
attributable to each spouse. Our base-case results apportion this
insurance using the imputation method described previously. If in some
cases these imputations falsely imply that insurance is held to protect
spouses who are not financially vulnerable, then our calculations will
overstate uninsured vulnerabilities for at-risk individuals. To examine
the potential significance of imputation error, we consider an extreme
alternative assumption: All life insurance is held to protect the
secondary earner (who is, in general, considerably more vulnerable). As
indicated in Table 10, the effects on our results are minimal. This is
not surprising for two reasons: Total household life insurance is
typically small relative to benchmark insurance, and, in any case, our
imputations attribute most life insurance to the primary earner.
If important economic variables are measured with error, our
calculations may overstate the thickness of the upper and lower tails of
the distribution of IMPACT, thereby exaggerating the frequencies of
significant and severe financial vulnerabilities. Measures of household
assets tend to be particularly noisy. However, as illustrated in the
final two rows of Table 10, our findings are not sensitive to moderate
changes in the values of wealth (a 20% increase or decrease).
As mentioned in section II, we have ignored the possibility that
remarriage might cushion the impact of a spouse's death. Bernheim
et al. (2003) report that remarriage occurs with low frequency among the
HRS sample, but it is probably more common for the younger households
included in the SCF. Because it is difficult to model the consequences
of remarriage, we did not conduct pertinent sensitivity analysis.
Consequently, we cannot rule out the possibility that low levels of
insurance among young households are attributable to the expectation
that a survivor will benefit financially from remarriage. However, this
hypothesis strikes us as odd. Even young individuals must consider the
risk that they may be unable or unwilling to remarry, the value of
retaining the option not to remarry, and the effect of financial status
on remarriage prospects.
Although our measures of uninsured financial vulnerabilities are
sensitive to certain critical assumptions, it is important to emphasize
that the poor correlation between coverage and vulnerability is robust.
From Table 10, we see that the change in the estimated incidence of
vulnerability is largest when we assume that there are no economies of
shared living, that housing expenditures are completely flexible, or
that all survivors work full time. However, for all of these alternative
scenarios, regressions analogous to those reported in section IV
continue to indicate that households with greater vulnerabilities
(measured by benchmark insurance) typically have no more coverage on
average, at any age, than those with greater vulnerabilities.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
Using the 1995 SCF and an elaborate lifecycle model, we have
quantified the potential financial impact of each individual's
death on his or her survivors, and we have measured the degree to which
life insurance moderates these consequences. We have found that life
insurance is essentially uncorrelated with financial vulnerability at
every stage of the life cycle. This finding is consistent with the
hypothesis that life insurance bears little relation to needs at the
time of purchase; however, it tends to refute the hypothesis that
households purchase long-term contracts with initially appropriate
insurance coverage but fail to adjust this coverage over time as their
circumstances change.
The impact of insurance among at-risk households is modest, and
substantial uninsured vulnerabilities are widespread, particularly among
younger couples. Nearly two-thirds of secondary earners between the ages
of 22 and 39 have significant financial vulnerabilities (projected
reductions in living standards exceeding 20%), and nearly one-third have
severe vulnerabilities (projected reductions exceeding 40%). Moreover,
only one in five of these at-risk households held sufficient life
insurance to avert significant or severe financial consequences.
Combining all age groups, 56% of secondary earners and 6% of primary
earners would have experienced significant or severe declines in living
standard on the death of a spouse in the absence of life insurance.
Actual life insurance holdings reduce these figures to, respectively,
42% and 5%. Thus, the overall impact of life insurance holdings on
financial vulnerabilities among at-risk households is modest. Roughly
two-thirds of poverty among surviving women and more than one-third of
poverty among surviving men results from a failure to ensure survivors
of an undiminished living standard through insurance.
We have also provided evidence of a significant gender bias in life
insurance holdings. Specifically, for any given level of financial
vulnerabilities, couples provide significantly more protection for wives
than for husbands. For example, couples with severely at-risk wives on
average hold $166,628 of life insurance, whereas couples with severely
at-risk husbands on average hold only 15% of this amount ($24,827).
ABBREVIATIONS
HRS: Health and Retirement Study
OECD: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
SCF: Survey of Consumer Finances
APPENDIX: DATA IMPUTATION
Nonasset Income
Our calculations require data on each spouse's past and future
covered earnings as well as future total (covered and uncovered)
earnings. We assume that all earnings are covered. For respondents who
were working at the survey date, we have 1995 self-reported labor
earnings. To impute past and future earnings we use a model that assumes
that the cross-section age-earnings profile for fully employed workers
remains constant through time. We allow real wages for all ages to grow
over time, using the historic Social Security real wage growth for past
years and a 1% overall real wage growth factor for future years. (In our
robustness analysis, was also look at a 0% and 2% overall real wage
growth factor for future years.) In estimating past earnings we assume
that the first year of employment is the maximum of 1951 and the year
the person was age 22.18 Households in which one of the spouses was
temporarily not working, as opposed to out of the labor force, were
dropped from our sample,
The SCF provides information on other kinds of non-asset income. We
treat some of these income sources, such as veteran's benefits,
Social Security, disability income, welfare, child support, and regular
help from friends or relatives, as nontaxable. Except for Social
Security disability income and child support, we assume these income
streams continue, with full adjustments for inflation, until the
respondent's death. Social Security disability income is assumed to
end at age 62, when the recipient becomes eligible for Social Security
retirement benefits. We divide child support received by the number of
children to obtain child support per child and assume it is received
until the child in question reaches age 18. (19) We treat other kinds of
special receipts, such as income from trust funds and royalties, as
taxable. We assume they will be received for 10 years beyond the survey
date and that the payments will be constant in nominal terms. Relatively
few respondents receive these kinds of income flows, and the amounts are
generally small relative to average earnings. We assume that SCF
respondents retire at their stated intended ages of retirement or age
70, whichever is smaller. For those who fail to say when they will
retire, we use age 65.
Pension Plans, Retirement Accounts, and Social Security
The SCF provides information on nominal benefits currently received
from defined benefit pension plans as well as expected nominal benefits
for future pension recipients. We assume that all pensions are indexed
to inflation and that a surviving spouse would receive 100% of the
monthly benefit or lump-sum distribution. We further assume that
employer-sponsored defined contribution plans and all private retirement
accounts (IRAs and Keoghs) provide for tax-deductible contributions and
tax-deferred accumulation. Contributions in all future years up to age
59 are set equal, in real terms, to contributions in the survey year. If
total contributions are greater than the legal limits ($30,000 or 25% of
income), contributions are truncated. The proportion given by the
employer remains constant. Any contributions (by the employee or the
employer) over the legal limit are included in employee nondeductible
and tax-favored contributions.
The SCF contains information on IRA account balances but not annual
contributions. We impute contributions based on tobit regressions from
the Consumer Expenditure Survey. Contributions are calculated as a
function of marital status, work status, age, earnings, and family size.
If an individual is already receiving Social Security benefits, we
assume that benefits have already started. Otherwise, we impute the
initial age of benefit receipt as follows. If the individual is still
working, we assume that benefits will start at his or her projected
retirement age (but not earlier than age 62). If the individual is
retired, we use the reported start date for those currently receiving
benefits; for those not yet receiving benefits, we assume benefits will
start at age 62 for those currently under 62, and at the current age for
those over 62. In all cases, the initial age of benefit receipt is
between 62 and 70. For respondents currently receiving Social Security
disability benefits, we assume that they switch to retirement benefits
at age 62.
Our calculations also require information on the age at which
individuals begin to receive private pension benefits. For those not yet
receiving benefits, we use the age at which the individual expects
benefits to begin as reported in the SCF.
Individuals with previous marriages lasting more than 10 years and
ending in divorce or separation and individuals with previous marriages
lasting more than 9 months and ending in the spouse's death are
eligible to receive Social Security benefits based on the earnings
history of their prior spouse. This presents a problem because we do not
have any information about prior spouses. We assume that all such
individuals receive benefits based on either their own earnings history
or that of their current spouse.
Housing
Our calculations require information on a variety of specific
housing expenditures, including mortgages, home insurance premiums,
property taxes, and other recurring expenses. Association fees,
homeowner or condo/coop/townhouse association fees, and rent on the site
for households owning and living in mobile homes are added to home
insurance premiums to form recurring house expenditures. When one owns
part of a farm, one is classified as a homeowner. The rent paid is then
also added to the insurance premium. The SCF does not contain
information on home insurance premiums. We imputed annual home insurance
premiums by multiplying the home value by 0.0025.
If the mortgage payment (minus property taxes and insurance premium
if respondent states these are included in their payments) is negative
then the observation is dropped. If the annual property tax is greater
than 5% of the home value, the observation is dropped.
With regard to mortgages, the SCF reports the balance remaining,
the number of years remaining, the interest rate, and the payment. To
ensure consistency, we imputed the balance remaining on the mortgage
based on the years remaining and the interest rate and payment.
In some instances, rental payments reported in the sample include
heat and electricity expenses; in such cases, respondents were not asked
separately about these utility payments. We apportion the reported
number into separate components by assuming that the ratio of rent to
utilities is the same for these respondents as the average ratio
computed from the HRS. If rent includes all utilities, rent is set to
0.77 * rent. If rent includes some utilities, rent is set to 0.89 *
rent. We have no information on utility expenditure if it is not
included in rent. The SCF does not include any information concerning
property taxes paid on second homes. We assume that this property is
taxed at the same rate as the primary home. Finally, we set monthly
rental payments equal to zero for the few respondents who report that
they live in a house or apartment that they neither rent nor own.
In addition, for our base case we assume that all households plan
to remain in the same house before and after retirement. One test of
robustness allows widows and widowers to move to smaller homes. For this
case we assume that the move to homes that are 70% of the size of their
previous homes.
Other Variables
For confidentiality reasons, the SCF does not report the
respondent's date or month of birth or state of residency. We
assume that each respondent was born on June 15. For the purposes of
computing state taxes, we use Massachusetts law. We set the maximum age
of life to 95 for all individuals. Many households have adult children
living with them. For the purposes of this project, only children age 18
or under are included.
We assume for all respondents a fixed amount for funeral expenses,
which is set equal to the median of the reported expenses ($5,000) for
HRS spouses who actually died in 1991 (90 observations). The HRS reports
information on actual funeral expenses and legal fees of deceased spouses. We set intended bequests equal to zero.
The SCF allows mortgages to end with a balloon payment. When there
is a balloon payment, we assume that they refinance for the amount of
the balloon payment with a 15-year mortgage (8% interest rate). There is
no space in ESPlanner for future mortgages, so these are included in
special expenditures. Interest payments on the first home are included
in deductible special expenditures. Payments on the balance are included
in nondeductible special expenditures. Nondeductible special
expenditures also include child support or alimony payment and support
to other family members. These are assumed to be paid in the current
year and the next four years (a total of five years).
As a measure of a household's net worth, we use total
nonhousing assets minus total nonhousing liabilities. Total nonhousing
assets include checking and saving accounts, money market funds,
certificates of deposit, government saving bonds, T bills, stocks,
mutual funds, investment trusts, business equity, bonds, bond funds,
real estate other than primary and vacation homes, the cash value of
life insurance policies, and some miscellaneous items. Total nonhousing
liabilities include personal loans, student loans, credit card balances,
car loans, installment loans, and other nonhousing debt. Housing debt
(mortgages and equity lines of credit) are considered separately. We
assume that apart from mortgages and other outstanding housing debt,
households cannot borrow against future income. For our base case, we
use a 3% rate of inflation and a 3% real pretax rate of return.
We assume respondents' borrowing limit is set equal to zero.
The expected change in living standard after retirement or in case
of death of one partner is set equal to zero.
TABLE 1
Sample Life Insurance Benchmarks
Insurance Insurance
Benchmark Benchmark
for Husband for Wife
Base case 285,922 0
+Age (50,48) 127,455 0
-Age (30,28) 607,446 0
+Husband's earnings ($60K) 382,239 0
-Husband's earnings ($30K) 187,457 32,581
+Wife's earnings ($40K) 225,430 52,606
-Wife's earnings ($20) 282,246 0
+Child (age 9) 298,016 0
-Child (only the 5-year-old) 295,732 0
+Earnings growth (2%) 327,984 0
-Earnings growth (0%) 240,957 0
+Real interest rate (5%) 210,364 0
-Real interest rate (1%) 409,454 0
Notes: Assumptions for base case: age of husband: 40,
age of wife: 38, husband's employee earnings: $45,000,
wife's employee earnings: $25,000, husband's retirement
age: 64, wife's retirement age: 63, number of children: 2,
age of children: 5 and 7, nonhousing net wealth: $50,000,
primary home value: $150,000, mortgage balance:
$120,000, earnings growth: 1%, real interest rate: 3%.
TABLE 2
Validation of the SCF Life Insurance Data
Percent Covered Mean Coverage (All
(All Life Insurance) Life Insurance)
LIMRA SCF LIMRA SCF
All households 78 85 132,304 163,973
Ages 18-24 47 51 92,222 96,438
Ages 25-34 75 80 149,476 159,916
Ages 35-44 85 87 202,150 203,759
Ages 45-54 83 92 159,569 200,058
Ages 55-64 83 86 96,567 105,441
65 and older 77 87 27,156 39,692
Note: Life Insurance Marketing Research Association (LIMRA) figures
are based on a 1992 survey (see American Council of Life Insurance,
1994), with mean coverage adjusted to 1995 dollars.
TABLE 3
Descriptive Statistics
Mean Median
Panel A: Household-Level Variables
Nonhousing net wealth 1,641,724 45,250
Primary home ownership 0.76 1
Primary home value 160,551 85,000
Household nonasset income 125,779 52,300
Total household life insurance, actual 206,022 71,000
Total household life insurance, benchmark 443,444 205,058
Number of children 0.97 1
Husband Wife
Mean Median Mean Median
Panel B: Individual-Level Variables
Age 44 43 42 41
Nonwhite 0.172 0
Gender 0 0 1 1
College degree 0.404 0 0.375 0
Pension coverage 0.716 1 0.538 1
Nonasset income 85,292 34,200 18,606 14,160
Imputed life ins. 166,215 54,391 39,806 14,685
Benchmark life ins. 405,916 149,535 37,528 0
[DELTA] liv. std., ignore
ins. (%) -5.66 0.00 -28.6 -21.5
[DELTA] liv. std., imputed
(%) -2.40 0.66 -16.3 -7.75
Primary Earner Secondary Earner
Mean Median Mean Median
Panel B: Individual-Level Variables
Age 43 43 42 41
Nonwhite
Gender 0.220 0 0.780 1
College degree 0.422 0 0.356 0
Pension coverage 0.750 1 0.504 1
Nonasset income 87,916 36,000 15,983 12,480
Imputed life ins. 160,539 47,597 45,483 15,598
Benchmark life ins. 415,229 168,224 28,214 0
[DELTA] liv. std., ignore
ins. (%) -3.77 0.00 -30.5 -24.6
[DELTA] liv. std., imputed
(%) -0.16 0.87 -18.5 -13.3
Notes: Imputed and benchmark life insurance refer to insurance on the
life of the individual listed at the top of the column. Changes in
living standard ([DELTA] liv. std.) for the spouse listed at the top
of each column depend on insurance on the life of the other spouse.
TABLE 4
Characteristics of Households with Different Levels of Benchmark
Insurance
Benchmark Fraction of Median Median
Household Households Percent Benchmark Actual
Insurance (%) Insured Insurance Insurance
Panel A. Insurance Levels (Household Aggregates)
$0 21.2 83.1 0 68,000
$1-199,999 28.4 81.2 97,972 39,000
$200,000-449,999 25.8 82.8 309,668 100,000
$450,000 or more 24.6 83.5 674,480 100,000
Median Median
Ratio Ratio
of of
Benchmark Actual
Insurance Insurance
Ratio of Benchmark Fraction of to to
Household Insurance Households Percent Household Household
to Household Earnings (%) Insured Earnings Earnings
Panel B. Ratios of Insurance to Earnings (Household Aggregates)
0 21.2 83.1 0 0.96
0 to 3.99 26.8 87.0 2.07 1.37
4 to 7.99 24.9 89.9 5.59 1.91
8 or more 27.1 71.1 12.57 1.09
Benchmark Mean Median Median
Household Benchmark Mean Actual Household Average Age
Insurance Insurance Insurance Earnings of Couple
Panel A. Insurance Levels (Household Aggregates)
$0 0 215,174 65,000 56
$1-199,999 99,073 106,499 35,360 46
$200,000-449,999 313,821 174,565 50,000 38
$450,000 or more 1,359,286 346,001 62,220 31
Mean Mean
Ratio Ratio
of of
Benchmark Actual
Insurance Insurance
Ratio of Benchmark to to Median Median
Household Insurance Household Household Household Average Age
to Household Earnings Earnings Earnings Earnings of Couple
Panel B. Ratios of Insurance to Earnings (Household Aggregates)
0 0 2.53 65,000 56
0 to 3.99 2.08 2.09 54,000 47
4 to 7.99 5.69 2.84 54,789 39
8 or more 15.03 2.86 37,901 30
TABLE 5
Regression Results, Actual Life
Insurance versus Benchmark Life
Insurance, Household Aggregates
Constant Benchmark
Panel A: Level of Actual Household Insurance
OLS 109,294.5 0.2181
(10,904.63) (0.0029)
Tobit 61,187.04 0.2187
(12,799.07) (0.0033)
Median regression 20,275.87 0.2202
(11,529.65) (0.0453)
Probit (probability scaled, using 0.0010
benchmark insurance/[10.sup.5]) (0.0021)
Panel B: Ratio of Life Insurance to Earnings
OLS 2.432 0.024
(0.2598) (0.0275)
Tobit 1.911 -0.042
(0.3057) (0.0341)
Median regression 1.487 -0.026
(0.1316) (0.0091)
Probit (probability scaled) -0.0093
(0.0015)
Note: Standard errors are given in parenthesis.
TABLE 6
Additional Regression Results, Actual Life Insurance versus Benchmark
Life Insurance, Household Aggregates
Median
OLS Tobit Reg. Probit
Benchmark insurance to -0.0485 -0.1923 -0.0524 -0.0102
household income (0.1057) (0.1355) (0.0337) (0.0059)
Average age of couple 0.0540 0.1374 0.0854 0.0195
(0.1390) (0.1701) (0.0507) (0.0077)
Average age of couple -0.0012 -0.0023 -0.0012 -0.0002
squared (0.0013) (0.0017) (0.0005) (0.0001)
Benchmark insurance to -0.0009 0.0034 0.0009 0.0001
income interacted with age (0.0034) (0.0042) (0.0012) (0.0002)
Age < 22 (group 1)
Age 22-40 (group 2)
Age 41-55 (group 3)
Age 56-70 (group 4)
Age 71+ (group 5)
Benchmark insurance to
earnings ratio interacted
with age group 1
Benchmark insurance to
earnings ratio interacted
with age group 2
Benchmark insurance to
earnings ratio interacted
with age group 3
Benchmark insurance to
earnings ratio interacted
with age group 4
Benchmark insurance to
earnings ratio interacted
with age group 5
Constant 2.7713 0.8826 0.3540
(3.43) (4.19) (1.3460)
p-raluefor tests
No relationship between 0.840 0.184 0.123 0.009
actual and benchmark at
any age
The relationship between 0.793 0.420 0.456 0.598
actual and benchmark is
the same at all ages
Median
OLS Tobit Reg. Probit
Benchmark insurance to
household income
Average age of couple
Average age of couple
squared
Benchmark insurance to
income interacted with age
Age < 22 (group 1) 0.15054 -1.7201 0.00 0.1367
(3.8696) (5.1116) (1.7100) (0.2005)
Age 22-40 (group 2) 3.4352 3.1355 2.2503 0.2959
(0.5222) (0.6250) (0.2103) (0.0295)
Age 41-55 (group 3) 2.2872 1.8239 1.5278 0.3293
(0.4705) (0.5415) (0.2209) (0.0305)
Age 56-70 (group 4) 1.6729 0.7231 0.6167 0.2340
(0.5756) (0.6674) (0.1167) (0.0330)
Age 71+ (group 5) 0.7924 -1.2351 0.2759 0.1109
(1.4840) (1.7915) (0.1381) (0.0750)
Benchmark insurance to 0.0458 -0.0405 0.00 -0.0077
earnings ratio interacted (0.1213) (0.1706) (0.0814) (0.0069)
with age group 1
Benchmark insurance to -0.0306 -0.1098 -0.0556 -0.0091
earnings ratio interacted (0.0408) (0.0510) (0.0128) (0.0222)
with age group 2
Benchmark insurance to 0.0738 0.0400 0.0362 -0.0083
earnings ratio interacted (0.1261) (0.1464) (0.0779) (0.0076)
with age group 3
Benchmark insurance to -0.0066 -0.0052 0.0348 0.0003
earnings ratio interacted (0.2239) (0.2575) (0.0632) (0.0131)
with age group 4
Benchmark insurance to -0.0368 0.2251 0.0750 0.0389
earnings ratio interacted (0.7363) (0.8592) (0.1057) (0.0443)
with age group 5
Constant
p-raluefor tests
No relationship between 0.958 0.435 0.002 0.001
actual and benchmark at
any age
The relationship between 0.925 0.864 0.287 0.794
actual and benchmark is
the same at all ages
Note: Standard errors are given in parentheses.
TABLE 7
Distribution of Changes (%) in Living Standard for Surviving Spouses
Surviving Spouses are
Wives Husbands
Ignoring Imputed Ignoring Imputed
IMPACT Insurance Insurance Insurance Insurance
Panel A: Husbands and Wives
< -40% 30.98 19.26 3.48 2.90
-40% to -20% 20.91 18.68 6.49 5.61
-20% to 0% 19.36 19.94 17.42 15.10
0% 28.75 5.32 72.60 12.29
0% to 20% -- 31.85 -- 63.12
20% to 40% -- 3.39 -- 0.68
>40% -- 1.55 -- 0.29
Observations 1,033 1,033 1,033 1,033
Surviving Spouses are
Secondary earners Primary earners
Ignoring Imputed Ignoring Imputed
IMPACT Insurance Insurance Insurance Insurance
Panel B: Primary and Secondary Earners
< -40% 32.53 20.62 1.94 1.55
-40% to -20% 23.33 21.10 4.07 3.19
-20% to 0% 20.52 22.17 16.26 12.88
0% 23.62 4.07 77.73 13.55
0% to 20% -- 27.49 -- 67.47
20% to 40% -- 3.00 -- 1.06
>40% -- 1.55 -- 0.29
Observations 1,033 1,033 1,033 1,033
TABLE 8
Effect of Life Insurance on Changes in Living Standards
for Surviving Spouses by Level of Vulnerability
Mean IMPACT
Range for
IMPACT, Ignoring Imputed
Surviving Ignoring Insurance Insurance
Spouses Are Insurance (%) (%)
Wives <-40% -65.5 -47.6
-40% to -20% -30.1 -17.2
-20% to 0% -10.3 1.68
0% 0.0 6.14
Husbands <-40% -68.4 -64.1
-40% to -20% -27.1 -23.4
-20% to 0% -8.7 -4.4
0% 0.0 2.9
Secondary earners <-40% -65.8 -49.1
-40% to -20% -29.8 -18.2
-20% to 0% -10.3 -0.3
0% 0.0 6.9
Primary earners <-40% -66.4 -53.2
-40% to -20% -26.8 -21.5
-20% to 0% -8.6 -3.1
0% 0.0 2.9
Range for Insurance Holdings
IMPACT,
Surviving Ignoring Percent Mean Mean
Spouses Are Insurance Uninsured Benchmark Actual
Wives <-40% 22.8 630,079 166,628
-40% to -20% 14.8 908.146 265,210
-20% to 0% 10.5 107,633 133,122
0% 18.2 0 116,059
Husbands <-40% 22.2 291,568 24,827
-40% to -20% 22.4 210,961 23,056
-20% to 0% 18.3 78,528 37,625
0% 16.7 0 42,545
Secondary earners <-40% 22.3 614,989 159,234
-40% to -20% 14.9 830,155 236,420
-20% to 0% 13.2 104,850 116,975
0% 16.8 0 125,237
Primary earners <-40% 30.0 274,272 35,598
-40% to -20% 26.2 243,488 44,115
-20% to 0% 15.5 79,962 51,181
0% 17.2 0 44,609
TABLE 9
Life Insurance Coverage and Financial Consequences for
Surviving Spouses: Selected Population Subgroups
Ratio of Actual-to-
Benchmark Insurance
(Household Totals)
Median-
Mean-to- to-
Mean Median
Full sample 0.465 0.346
HH earnings < $15K 0.145 0.041
HH earnings $15-45K 0.333 0.116
HH earnings $45-100K 0.465 0.381
HH earnings > $100K 0.522 1.62
Dual earners 0.508 0.345
Single earners 0.428 0.491
Earnings diff. 1-1 to 2-1 0.503 0.384
Earnings diff. over 4-1 0.440 0.364
Age of survivor < 22 0.056 0.000
Age of survivor 22-39 0.276 0.196
Age of survivor 40-55 0.825 0.813
Age of survivor 56-70 2.57 NA *
Age of survivor > 71 16.8 NA *
No children 0.605 0.538
One or more child 0.411 0.349
Whites 0.463 0.403
Nonwhites 0.483 0.150
Consequences for Secondary Earners
Severe (>40%) Significant (>20%)
Frequency Fraction Frequency Fraction
(%) Addressed (%) Addressed
Full sample 20.6 0.366 41.7 0.254
HH earnings < $15K 46.2 0.143 53.9 0.159
HH earnings $15-45K 30.1 0.246 51.6 0.161
HH earnings $45-100K 15.0 0.481 40.0 0.292
HH earnings > $100K 9.52 0.555 22.0 0.449
Dual earners 17.1 0.385 41.9 0.273
Single earners 26.7 0.290 41.4 0.217
Earnings diff. 1-1 to 2-1 9.07 0.426 35.5 0.300
Earnings diff. over 4-1 28.0 0.344 43.6 0.219
Age of survivor < 22 60.0 0.000 90.0 0.000
Age of survivor 22-39 31.1 0.344 62.6 0.203
Age of survivor 40-55 11.9 0.500 27.6 0.320
Age of survivor 56-70 7.64 0.293 13.4 0.298
Age of survivor > 71 8.82 0.000 11.8 0.197
No children 19.2 0.286 37.2 0.200
One or more child 22.0 0.280 46.0 0.290
Whites 20.1 0.389 40.9 0.266
Nonwhites 23.0 0.256 45.5 0.198
Consequences for Primary Earners
Severe (>40%) Significant (>20%)
Frequency Fraction Frequency Fraction
(%) Addressed (%) Addressed
Full sample 1.55 0.201 4.74 0.210
HH earnings < $15K 5.13 0.080 5.13 0.000
HH earnings $15-45K 2.73 0.080 7.65 0.125
HH earnings $45-100K 0.65 0.000 3.91 0.308
HH earnings > $100K 0.60 0.000 0.60 0.496
Dual earners 1.69 0.214 5.99 0.250
Single earners 1.31 0.510 2.62 0.090
Earnings diff. 1-1 to 2-1 2.59 0.167 9.07 0.238
Earnings diff. over 4-1 1.02 0.171 2.04 0.093
Age of survivor < 22 0.00 0.000 9.09 0.000
Age of survivor 22-39 1.67 0.301 6.70 0.200
Age of survivor 40-55 0.71 0.245 2.12 0.000
Age of survivor 56-70 0.67 0.000 2.01 0.250
Age of survivor > 71 16.7 0.000 26.7 0.000
No children 1.98 0.168 6.14 0.162
One or more child 1.14 0.070 3.41 0.281
Whites 1.17 0.287 4.21 0.217
Nonwhites 3.37 0.000 7.30 0.188
Note: * Median benchmark insurance is zero for these groups.
TABLE 10
Frequency of Severe and Significant Financial Consequences
for Surviving Spouses: Robustness (Full Sample)
Ratio of Actual-to-Benchmark
Insurance (Household Totals)
Mean-to-Mean Median-to-Median
Base case 0.465 0.346
Real interest rate = 1% 0.333 0.239
Real interest rate = 5% 0.610 0.462
Baseline wage growth rate = 0% 0.537 0.401
Baseline wage growth rate = 2% 0.403 0.306
Maximum lifespan = 85 0.473 0.352
Consumption growth rate = 1% 0.484 0.366
Consumption growth rate = -1% 0.450 0.342
No ecs. of shared living
([alpha] = 1) 0.877 1.14
Survivor receives 50%
pension benefits 0.435 0.300
Housing completely fungible 0.552 0.513
Survivor downsizes house by 30% 0.503 0.422
Survivors fully employed 0.533 0.569
All life insurance assigned to
the primary earner 0.465 0.346
Wealth reduced by 20% 0.446 0.337
Wealth increased by 20% 0.484 0.357
Consequences for Secondary Earners
(Imputed Insurance) (%)
Severe (>40%) Significant (>20%)
Base case 20.6 41.7
Real interest rate = 1% 23.9 44.2
Real interest rate = 5% 19.3 38.5
Baseline wage growth rate = 0% 19.8 40.0
Baseline wage growth rate = 2% 22.6 42.9
Maximum lifespan = 85 20.5 41.2
Consumption growth rate = 1% 20.2 39.9
Consumption growth rate = -1% 21.1 42.5
No ecs. of shared living
([alpha] = 1) 14.7 26.2
Survivor receives 50%
pension benefits 22.3 45.3
Housing completely fungible 10.8 28.3
Survivor downsizes house by 30% 18.5 36.9
Survivors fully employed 11.5 29.6
All life insurance assigned to
the primary earner 19.9 38.8
Wealth reduced by 20% 21.3 43.1
Wealth increased by 20% 20.2 40.9
Consequences for Primary Earners
(Imputed Insurance) (%)
Severe (>40%) Significant (>20%)
Base case 1.55 4.74
Real interest rate = 1% 1.92 5.19
Real interest rate = 5% 1.35 4.15
Baseline wage growth rate = 0% 1.65 4.55
Baseline wage growth rate = 2% 1.45 5.14
Maximum lifespan = 85 1.45 4.66
Consumption growth rate = 1% 1.45 4.17
Consumption growth rate = -1% 1.55 5.02
No ecs. of shared living
([alpha] = 1) 0.77 1.84
Survivor receives 50%
pension benefits 1.65 4.84
Housing completely fungible 0.38 2.00
Survivor downsizes house by 30% 1.16 4.07
Survivors fully employed 1.45 4.65
All life insurance assigned to
the primary earner 1.94 6.00
Wealth reduced by 20% 1.54 4.73
Wealth increased by 20% 1.45 4.45
(1.) Our base-case calculations assume that an individual does not
increase hours worked in the labor force after the death of his or her
spouse.
(2.) To calculate this decline, we make use of an elaborate
life-cycle model. The model is embodied in financial planning software,
Economic Security Planner (ESPlanner). Economic Security Planning, Inc.,
provides free copies of the software for academic research. For
additional information, consult www.ESPlanner.com
(3.) In the special case in which the household has Leontief
preferences (defined over per capita adjusted expenditures), this is
also the utility maximizing outcome.
(4.) Note that when actual life insurance is below the benchmark,
the intact couple saves on insurance premiums, so its actual consumption
exceeds [c.sup.*]. Hence, the IMPACT variables understate the change in
living standard that an individual experiences on a spouse's death.
However, because life insurance premiums typically account for a small
fraction of expenditures, the degree of understatement is small.
(5.) A nonnegativity constraint for life insurance purchases is
equivalent to the restriction that life annuities are not available for
purchase at the margin. For further discussion, see Yaari (1965),
Kotlikoff and Spivak (1981), and Bernheim (1987).
(6.) Formally, one can think of the outcome that we identify as the
limit of the solutions to a series of utility maximization problems in
which the intertemporal elasticity of substitution approaches zero. In
the limit (the Leontief case), the household is actually indifferent with respect to the distribution of consumption across any years in
which its living standard exceeds the minimum level.
(7.) Our child-adult equivalency factor is that used by the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (see
Ringen, 1991). Nelson's (1992) work suggests a smaller value, but
she considers total household expenditures, whereas our child-adult
equivalency factor applies only to nonhousing consumption expenditure;
for our base-case results, we treat housing expenditure as inflexible.
It appears from Nelson's work that a higher equivalency factor is
appropriate for nonhousing expenditures.
(8.) The OECD uses a value of 0.7 for [alpha] (see Ringen, 1991).
Williams et al. (1998) consider values of 0.5 for both [alpha] and
[beta].
(9.) The SCF does not contain data on the state of residency.
Therefore, we assume all households reside in Massachusetts.
(10.) For additional examples and for comparisons with
recommendations generated by Quicken Financial Planner, see Gokhale et
al. (2001).
(11.) Even with risk aversion, such choices are reasonable if load
factors are low. For evidence 6n load factors in the context of life
annuities, see Mitchell et al. (1999).
(12.) Kennickell (1991) provides a description of the imputation
procedure.
(13.) Scaling the insurance variables by earnings is, of course, a
perfect control for earnings only if the earnings elasticity of
insurance purchases is unity. When an earnings variable (either levels
or logs) is added to the list of explanatory variables for any
specification in Table 5, the results change relatively little.
(14.) Formally, fraction addressed = [(Frequency given insurance =
0)-(Frequency given actual insurance)]/ (Frequency given insurance = 0).
(15.) The age-adjusted frequencies of severe and significant
uninsured financial exposures reported here and in Bernheim et al.
(2003) are lower than Auerbach and Kotlikoff's (1987: 1991a; 1991b)
estimates. Possible explanations for the disparity include increases in
female labor force participation since the 1960s, changes in patterns of
insurance coverage, and methodological differences.
(16.) For our base case, we assume that the inflation rate and real
interest rate are both 3%.
(17.) In this exercise, we assume that the financing for the new
house is the same as the continuation financing for the old house.
Consequently, on a spouse's death, the decline in home equity
equals the reduction in the value of the home, and there is an
offsetting increase in nonhousing assets; mortgage payments are
unchanged, but other housing expenses fall by 30%.
(18.) For workers who were under age 22 in 1995. we assume that
1995 was their first year of employment.
(19.) The SCF reports only the sum of child support and spousal
support. However, we confine our attention to couples, 98% of which are
married. Because spousal support generally ends on remarriage (and also
declines somewhat on average when individuals become unmarried
partners), we can safely assume that the entire reported amount is child
support.
REFERENCES
American Council of Life Insurance. 1994 Life Insurance Fact Book.
Washington, DC: American Council of Life Insurance, 1994.
--. 1999 Life Insurance Fact Book. Washington, DC: American Council
of Life Insurance, 1999.
Auerbach, A. J., and L. J. Kotlikoff. "Life Insurance of the
Elderly: Its Adequacy and Determinants," in Work, Health, and
Income among the Elderly, edited by G. Burtless. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution, 1987.
--. "Life Insurance Inadequacy--Evidence from a Sample of
Older Widows." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
No. 3765, 1991a.
--. "The Adequacy of Life Insurance Purchases." Journal
of Financial Intermediation, 1(3). 1991b, 215-41.
Bernheim, B. D. "The Economic Effects of Social Security:
Towards a Reconciliation of Theory and Measurement." Journal of
Public Economics, 33(3), 1987, 273-304.
Bernheim, B. D. L. Forni, J. Gokhale, and L. J. Kotlikoff.
"The Mismatch between Life Insurance Holdings and Financial
Vulnerabilities: Evidence from the Health and Retirement Survey."
American Economic Review, 93(1), 2003, 354-365.
Caplin, A. "The Reverse Mortgage Market: Problems and
Prospects," in Innovations in Managing the Financial Risks of
Retirement, edited by Z. Bodie, B. Hammond, O. Mitchell, and S. Zeldes.
Pension Research Council, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania,
2001.
Gokhale, J., L. J. Kotlikoff, and M. Warshawsky. "Comparing
the Economic and Conventional Approaches to Financial Planning," in
Essays on Sa ring, Bequests, Altruism, and Life-Cycle Planning, edited
by L. J. Kotlikoff. Chicago, IL: MIT Press, 2001, 489-560.
Holden, K. C., R. V. Burkhauser, and D. A. Myers.
"Pensioners' Annuity Choice: Is the Well-Being of Their Widows
Considered?" University of Wisconsin Institute for Research on
Poverty Discussion Paper 802 86, 1986.
Hurd, M. D., and D. A. Wise. "The Wealth and Poverty of
Widows: Assets before and after the Husband's Death," in The
Economics of Aging, edited by D. Wise. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1989, 177-99.
Kennickell, A. "Imputation of the 1989 Survey of Consumer
Finances: Stochastic Relaxation and Multiple Imputation." Mimeo,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1991.
Kotlikoff, L. J., and A. Spivak. "The Family as an Incomplete
Annuities Market." Journal of Political Economy, 89(2), 1981,
372-91.
Lundberg, S. "Family Bargaining and Retirement Behavior,"
in Behavioral Economics and Retirement Policy, edited by H. Aaron.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1999.
Mitchell, O. S., J. M. Poterba, M. J. Warshawsky, and J. R. Brown.
KNew Evidence on the Money's Worth of Individual Annuities."
American Economic Review, 89(5), 1999, 1299-318
Nelson, J. A. "Methods of Estimating Household Equivalence
Scales: An Empirical Investigation." Review of Income and Wealth,
38(3), 1992.
Ringen, S. "Households, Standard of Living, and
Inequality." Review of Income and Wealth, 37, 1991, 1-13.
Venti, S., and D. Wise. "Patterns of Housing Equity Use among
the Elderly," in Innovations in Managing the Financial Risks of
Retirement, edited by Z. Bodie, B. Hammond, O. Mitchell, and S. Zeldes.
Pension Research Council, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania,
200l.
Williams, R., D. Weiner, and F. Sammartino. "Equivalence
Scales, the Income Distribution, and Federal Taxes." Technical
Paper Series 1999-2, Congressional Budget Office, October 1998.
Yaari, M. "Uncertain Lifetime, Life Insurance, and the Theory
of the Consumer." Review of Economic Studies, 32, 1965, 137-50.
B. DOUGLAS BERNHEIM, KATHERINE GRACE CARMAN, JAGADEESH GOKHALE, and
LAURENCE J. KOTLIKOFF *
* We are grateful to the National Institute of Aging provided
financial support. Economic Security Planner (ESPlanner) is used in this
study with the permission of Economic Security Planning, Inc.
Bernheim: Professor, Department of Economics, Stanford University,
Stanford, CA 94305-6072 and National Bureau of Economic Research. Phone
650-725-8732, Fax 650-725-570, E-mail
[email protected]
Carman: Postdoctoral Fellow, Center for Basic Research in the
Social Sciences, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138. Phone
617-495-5365.
Gokhale: Senior Economic Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101-1387. Phone 216-579-2970,
Fax 216-579-3050, E-mail
[email protected]
Kotlikoff: Professor, Boston University, Department of Economics,
270 Bay State Rd., Boston, MA 02215. Phone 617-353-4002, Fax
617-353-4001, E-mail
[email protected]