The effects of financial education in the workplace: evidence from a survey of employers.
Bayer, Patrick J. ; Bernheim, B. Douglas ; Scholz, John Karl 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Since the early work of Mincer (1958), economists studying the
returns to education have traditionally focused on the relation between
education and wages. From the perspective of the associated literature,
education creates value by conferring skills that are of use to
employers. Clearly, however, this is not the sole economic objective of
education. In addition to labor market skills, education may also confer
decision-making skills. Apart from any effect on labor market
performance, these decision-making skills may improve an
individual's ability to weigh alternatives, exploit opportunities,
and achieve personal objectives.
Some of the most complex decisions undertaken by ordinary
individuals concern financial issues, such as the determination of
retirement income needs, or the allocation of resources among
alternative investments. Most individuals make these decisions on the
basis of their own judgment, rather than with the help of experts, in
large part because the market for financial expertise is imperfect (Bernheim 1994, 1998). It is therefore conceivable that appropriate
forms of education may improve the quality of personal financial
decision making.
Previous studies have documented correlations between an
individual's general level of educational attainment and his or her
rate of saving; for example, Bernheim and Scholz (1993) and Dynan,
Skinner, and Zeldes (2004). However, as in the literature on returns to
education in labor markets, these correlations may be attributable to
other factors. For example, individuals with greater patience presumably tend to remain in school longer and to save at higher rates. As noted by
those studying the relation between wages and schooling (e.g., Card
1995), causal inferences about the effects of education are potentially
misleading unless they are derived from sources of variation in
education that are plausibly exogenous.
A particularly pertinent source of variation in education concerns
the availability of financial education in the workplace. According to one survey, as of 1994, 88% of large employers offered some form of
financial education, and more than two-thirds had added these programs
after 1990. (1) Typically, employers provide information and guidance on
a range of topics related to retirement planning. Nearly all such
programs cover principles of asset allocation; 73% treat retirement
income needs and 88% discuss retirement strategies (Employee Benefit
Research Institute 1995). If, as argued by Bernheim (1994, 1995), low
saving frequently results from a failure to appreciate economic
vulnerabilities, then education of this form could have a powerful
effect on rates of saving.
It is doubtful that the availability of employer-based retirement
education is entirely unrelated to workers' underlying
predispositions to save. However, there are a variety of reasons
(discussed below) to believe that employers adopt these programs as
remedial measures in instances where employees are disinclined to save.
If this is the case, then cross-sectional estimates of the relation
between saving and education may provide lower bounds on the causal
effects of education. In addition, since many of these programs have
been adopted quite recently, it may be possible to control for an
unobserved predisposition to save by contrasting the behavior of the
same individuals before and after educational interventions.
In this article, we study the behavioral effects of financial
education in the workplace using survey data collected from employers
who sponsor pension plans. Our analysis is based in part on estimates of
the cross-sectional relations between various forms of education and
plan activity. Since the data contain repeated observations on many
firms, they also permit us to evaluate the direction of the probable
bias in cross-sectional estimates by testing the hypothesis that
education is remedial (through an examination of the circumstances under
which programs are adopted or expanded). Moreover, the longitudinal data
allow us to control explicitly for unobserved (firm-level) fixed
effects.
When we completed the first version of this article 12 yr ago
(Bayer, Bernheim, and Scholz 1996), (2) the evidence on this topic was
largely confined to qualitative surveys and case studies (e.g., A.
Foster Higgins & Co., Inc. 1994; Borleis and Wedell 1994; Employee
Benefit Research Institute 1994, 1995; Geisel 1995). The only exception
was a contemporaneous article by Bernheim and Garrett (1996, 2003),
which used household survey data to study the effects of financial
education in the workplace. As we discuss below, that analysis is
complementary to the current article. These two studies initiated a
strand of literature concerning the effects of adult financial education
on financial behavior. Subsequent contributions include Clark and
Schieber (1998), Clancy, Grinstein-Weiss, and Schreiner (2001), Duflo
and Saez (2003), Muller (2001-2002), Clark and D'Ambrosio (2003,
2007), Lusardi (2004), Maki (2004), Hira and Loibla (2005), Sherraden
and Boshara (2007), and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (2007).
This growing body of work is closely related to several other
strands of the literature. One strand, initiated by Bernheim, Garrett,
and Maki (1997, 2001), examines the effects of high school financial
curriculum mandates on adult financial decisions; see also Tennyson and
Nguyen (2001), Mandell (2007), and Cole and Shastry (2007). A second
strand studies the effects of financial knowledge and/or planning on
behavior; see Bernheim (1994, 1995, 1998), Lusardi (2000), Hogarth and
Hilgert (2002), Hilgert, Hogarth, and Beverly (2003), Courchane and Zorn
(2005), Lusardi and Mitchell (2007), and Cole and Shastry (2007). A
third strand investigates the accuracy of knowledge or expectations
concerning matters pertaining to retirement, such as social security
benefits, pension characteristics, or the timing of retirement; see
Bernheim (1988, 1989), Lusardi (1999), Gustman and Steinmeier (2001),
and Sunden (2006). A fourth strand concerns the measurement of financial
literacy; see, for example, Mandell (2006). A final strand, surveyed by
Martin (2007), examines the effectiveness of credit counseling.
The remainder of this article is organized as follows. After
describing our data (Section II), we provide an analysis of the
circumstances under which employers offer retirement education (Section
III). While certain kinds of education are more common at organizations
that offer self-directed pension plans (such as 401(k)s and 403(b)s),
even employers that offer defined benefit plans (and nothing else)
frequently provide some form of financial education. For 401(k) plans,
in particular, the data indicate that low participation among non-highly
compensated (NHC) employees is a strong predictor of the adoption and/or
enhancement of educational offerings. At least in the context of 401(k)
plans, education therefore appears to be remedial in the sense that it
is made available to those who are least inclined to save. In part, this
may be a consequence of nondiscrimination requirements, which limit
contributions of highly compensated (HC) employees as a function of
contributions by NHC employees. Based on this finding, one would expect
cross-sectional estimates of the relation between participation
(contributions) and education to be biased against the conclusion that
education enhances participation and contributions to self-directed
plans.
In Section IV, we examine factors correlated with participation in
and contributions to 401(k) plans. We find that both measures of
activity are significantly higher when employers offer retirement
seminars. The effect is much stronger for NHC employees than for HC
employees. The frequency of seminars emerges as a particularly important
correlate of behavior. We are unable to detect any effects of written
materials, such as newsletters and summary plan descriptions, regardless
of frequency. We obtain similar results based on longitudinal patterns
as well as for an assortment of estimation methods. In light of the
likely bias mentioned in the previous paragraph and discussed in more
detail in Section III, these findings are strongly consistent with the
efficacy of retirement seminars, and they do not rule out the
possibility that other forms of education are also effective.
In studying the relation between 401(k) activity and education, we
control for a variety of plan features. The effects of these features
are, of course, of independent interest and have been the subject of
several prior analyses (Andrews 1992; Beshears et. al. 2007; Choi,
Laibson, and Madrian 2004; Kusko, Poterba, and Wilcox 1998; Madrian and
Shea 2001; Papke 1995; Papke, Petersen, and Poterba 1996; Poterba,
Venti, and Wise 1994; Scott 1997). Generally, we find that the existence
of an employee match is strongly related to 401(k) contributions, and
especially to participation, in cross sections. However, this effect is
not readily apparent in longitudinal data. There is relatively little
indication that any measure of 401(k) activity is significantly related
to loan provisions. Investment options have no detectable effect on
participation, but contributions tend to be a bit higher when greater
flexibility is offered.
The article closes with a brief conclusion.
II. DATA
The data for our analysis come from the 1993 to 1994 versions of
the KPMG Peat Marwick Retirement Benefits Survey. In 1993, KPMG Peat
Marwick selected approximately 1,100 employers at random from a list of
all the private and public employers in the United States with at least
200 employees. If they were willing to participate again, these same
employers were retained for the 1994 survey. Any employers who declined
to participate in 1994 were replaced with a randomly selected employer
from the same industry, region, and employer-size category.
In each year, these employers were questioned by telephone about
the administration, features, and employee utilization of their
retirement plans. Some basic employer data, such as total employees,
sales, and industry, are available for all respondents. In addition,
those employers who have a retirement plan (910 in 1993 and 861 in 1994)
provide some general information about their plan, including the number
of employees covered by the plan, the types of plans offered, and the
extent to which financial education and guidance are provided by the
employer to help employees invest for retirement. Furthermore, for each
type of retirement plan that a firm offers, the survey contains detailed
questions about its features, eligibility requirements, and employee
activity.
Those employers who offer 401(k) plans (596 in 1993 and 566 in
1994) report the features of their plan, including the availability of
an employer match, the matching rate provided, whether hardship
withdrawals and loans are permitted, and the number and type of
investment options available to a participant in the plan. The survey
also allows us to determine which employee groups, such as union,
salaried, or part-time employees, are eligible to participate in the
plan. In addition, participation and contribution rates are provided for
the employees eligible for the 401(k) plan. Thus, for a large sample of
more than 500 firms each year, the survey provides a rich set of plan
characteristics and utilization rates.
The variables that we focus on in this study fall into three
categories: basic firm characteristics (where the firm is the unit of
analysis for the study); general plan characteristics, encompassing all
retirement plans offered by the firm; and 401(k) plan characteristics.
With respect to the first category, we experimented with a number of
basic firm characteristics (including sales and dummy variables for
industry and region), but generally found that they had very little
effect on our results. For most of the results presented in this
article, we have retained only one general firm characteristic: the
total number of employees. (3)
The second group of variables include general features of the
firm's retirement programs. The most important of these describe
the extent to which the firm provides financial education to its
employees. Specifically, the survey asks each respondent how often the
firm provides summary plan descriptions, employee newsletters or other
periodic publications, investment seminars for all employees, seminars
for employees older than 50 yr, and seminars for employees within a year
or two of retirement. Each respondent was asked whether the firm used
these devices often, sometimes, rarely, or never. To incorporate the
qualitative nature of these responses into our analysis, we use these
responses to create three dummy variables for each educational device.
The first indicates whether the device is used often, the second
indicates whether it is used sometimes or rarely, and the third
indicates it is never used. We combine the responses
"sometimes" and "rarely" because the data have
limited ability to identify educational parameters and because the
subjective distinctions between these responses seem the most likely to
differ across respondents. (4)
Other pertinent characteristics of an employer's overall
retirement program covered by the survey include information on the
composition of retirement plans (e.g., 401(k)s, defined benefit, profit
sharing) and the fraction of employees who are covered by a retirement
plan. Unfortunately, the survey collects coverage information on a
firm-wide basis rather than plan by plan.
The final category of variables includes characteristics of 401(k)
plans. These include dummy variables for whether loans are permitted and
whether an employer match is provided. We also calculate a measure of
the number of different kinds of investment options (employer stock,
guaranteed income contracts, equity mutual funds, corporate bond funds,
government funds, and other funds) available to plan participants. Other
survey questions allow us to determine if certain employee groups, such
as union, part time, or salaried employees, are eligible for the plan.
(5)
For 401(k) plans, we construct participation and contribution rates
for eligible employees. The survey provides measures of 401(k) plan
activity for three categories of employees: all, HC, and NHC. All
eligible employees are classified as either HC or NHC according to
specific rules set forth in the applicable nondiscrimination provisions.
These rules were instituted to ensure an equitable distribution of
benefits from pension plans. In the context of 401(k)s, they operate by
limiting the amounts that HC employees can contribute as a function of
contributions by NHC employees. An individual is classified as HC if he
or she meets any of a number of specific criteria (e.g., earnings of
roughly $100,000 or more, ownership of more than 5% of the company, or
earnings of roughly $65,000 or more if this amount is in the top
quintile of the firm's salary distribution). In addition to
participation rates, the survey also provides contribution rates as a
percentage of salary for plan participants. (6) Once again these figures
are provided separately for all employees, HC employees, and NHC
employees. Taking the product of participation rates and average
contribution rates conditional on participation, we obtain average
contribution rates conditional on eligibility.
Summary statistics for 401(k) participation and contribution rates
are provided in Table 1. Mean participation rates are slightly less than
60% for NHC employees, roughly 80% for HC employees, and just more than
60% overall in both 1993 and 1994. The distribution of participation
rates for HC employees is highly skewed (with outliers on the lower
tail), causing the median participation rates to be about 10 percentage
points higher than the mean rates. Participating employees generally
contribute between 5% and 7% of their salaries, with HC employees
contributing approximately one percentage point more than NHC employees.
In both years, contribution rates for eligible employees averaged less
than 3% for NHC employees, more than 5% for HC employees, and between 3%
and 4% overall.
III. THE AVAILABILITY OF RETIREMENT EDUCATION
As a first step in our analysis, we provide descriptive information
concerning the availability of different kinds of retirement education
in the workplace. Overall, in 1993, nearly 74% of pension plan sponsors
provided summary plan descriptions, roughly 65% distributed newsletters,
and more than 44% offered retirement seminars to all employees. When
firms are weighted by total employment, summary plan descriptions and
newsletters appear to be somewhat more common (roughly 80% in each
case), but the frequency of seminars is essentially unchanged (44%). The
fraction of firms providing summary plan descriptions was somewhat lower
in 1994 than in 1993, but the fractions providing newsletters and
seminars rose slightly.
Since our ultimate objective is to evaluate the relation between
education and behavior, it is important to develop an understanding of
the sources of variation in educational offerings across firms. Plan
sponsors are presumably more likely to provide information when
participants are required to make decisions. It is therefore natural to
speculate that the growth of educational offerings results in large part
from the rising popularity of self-directed plans such as 401(k)s and
403(b)s (see Employee Benefit Research Institute 1995, or the extended
discussion in Section III of Bernheim and Garrett 2003). Yet, the KPMG
Peat Marwick survey data reveal that seminars, newsletters, and summary
plan descriptions are nearly as common among firms with defined benefit
plans (43.8%, 68.9%, and 73.1%, respectively, for 1993) as among firm
with 401(k)s (44.4%, 71.2%, and 80.1%, respectively, for 1993).
The preceding finding raises the possibility that many employers
provide retirement education to address general concerns about
employees' preparation for retirement rather than to equip them
with plan-specific decisionmaking skills. One need not construe this as
necessarily altruistic. Education may help employees to appreciate the
values of their pension plans. By promoting adequate preparation for
retirement, an employer may also hope to avoid subsequent conflicts
(e.g., over demands for more generous pension benefits) with older,
poorly prepared workers. Assistance with financial planning may also
enhance employee loyalty, improve labor relations, and boost morale.
Of course, comparisons based on raw frequencies, such as those
described above, may be misleading. For example, it is common for
employers to offer both a defined benefit plan and a supplemental
401(k). It is therefore possible that the frequency of educational
offerings at organizations with defined benefit plans in part reflects
the presence of secondary 401(k) plans. Also, it is conceivable that
educational offerings may differ systematically by company
characteristics that are related to the presence of a defined benefit
plan.
To investigate this possibility, we estimate probit models
explaining the availability of seminars for all employees, seminars for
employees older than 50 yr, seminars for employees nearing retirement,
summary plan descriptions, and newsletters or periodicals. Results are
contained in Table 2. Explanatory variables include variables measuring
the types and variety of plans (where the omitted category is "only
a defined benefit plan"), employment, plan coverage, and year. The
data are pooled across years and the standard errors are corrected to
account for potential correlation across observations from the same
organization.
Focusing attention on organizations with a single plan, it is
evident that seminars of all kinds are most common among nonprofit institutions with 403(b)s. Companies with 401(k)s are more likely to
offer seminars to all employees than companies with defined benefit or
other kinds of plans but less likely to offer seminars specifically for
older employees. Written materials of all kinds are most commonly used
among companies with 401 (k)s, but there are no significant differences
between the likelihoods that sponsors of other kinds of plans provide
such materials. Thus, while the rising popularity of self-directed plans
may have promoted the growth of certain educational offerings, the
impetus for this growth appears to be much more general. This is
consistent with the findings of Bernheim and Garrett (2003).
Table 2 also indicates that educational offerings are significantly
more common among organizations with multiple plans. Employment and
coverage are positively correlated with seminar offerings but not with
the availability of written materials. This may reflect the presence of
economies of scale in the provision of seminars. Generally, the
frequencies of educational offerings did not change appreciably between
1993 and 1994.
When analyzing the relation between education and behavior, we must
necessarily restrict attention to organizations with plans that permit
employees to make choices. We therefore focus our attention on 401(k)s.
Since the determinants of education offerings relate to the selection
process determining the incidence of "treatment," it is
important to reexamine the determinants of these offerings specifically
in the context of 401(k)s. If, for example, education tends to be
offered in response to a demand for information by employees who are
naturally inclined to save at high rates, then positive cross-sectional
correlations between education and 401(k) activity could reflect
selection rather than the influence of employer-based education on
employee behavior. If, on the other hand, companies tend to provide
education as a remedial measure to employees who are otherwise
disinclined to save, then the nature of selection could obscure an
underlying relation between education and behavior.
Analogously to Table 2, Table 3 provides estimates of probit models
explaining the availability of various educational offerings in the
pooled 1993/1994 sample. In this instance, however, we have confined
attention to companies with 401(k)s. We have also added several new
explanatory variables, including the number of categories of investment
options (e.g., employer stock, guaranteed income contracts, bond funds,
equity mutual funds) available to participants and dummy variables
indicating whether the plan covers union employees, (7) whether it
provides for an employer match, and whether loans are permitted.
As in Table 2, seminars for older workers are more likely when
companies offer plans other than 401(k)s, and the likelihood of seminar
offerings generally tends to rise with employment. Notably, education
does not appear to be more common among plans that cover union
employees. Since employees presumably have greater leverage when they
are unionized, this casts doubt on the hypothesis that education is
provided in response to employee demand. It is also notable that the
correlation between seminars and employer matching provisions is
negative (though not significant at conventional levels). This is
consistent with the view that education and matching are substitutable
methods of encouraging participation in situations where employees show
insufficient interest in the plan. Not surprisingly, education of all
forms is significantly more likely when employers offer participants
more investment options. There is also some indication that seminars and
loan provisions are positively correlated.
Thus far, we have not exploited the longitudinal features of our
data. Doing so permits us to examine the circumstances under which
employers establish or expand educational offerings. Specifically, we
regress the change in seminar offerings between 1993 and 1994 on a
variety of "initial" (1993) company and pension plan
characteristics. For the purpose of this analysis, we measure the change
in seminar offerings as the difference between the "intensity"
of seminars (measured on a scale of 0-3) in 1993 and 1994 (see footnote 4).
Results are shown in Table 4. Separate results are presented for
each of our five educational categories. The most striking feature of
this table is the pattern of negative coefficients for the initial
participation rate of NHC employees in the specifications explaining
changes in seminar offerings. In the case of seminars for all employees,
the coefficient is highly significant; it is marginally significant
(i.e., with slightly less than 95% confidence) for the other two seminar
variables. This implies that low participation among NHC employees is
strongly associated with subsequent increases in employer-sponsored
seminars. This result does not, however, carry over to written
materials. No other variable consistently passes tests for statistical
significance at conventional levels. The coefficients of the initial HC
participation rate are also negative for the seminar variables, but
their magnitudes and levels of significance are smaller. With low
confidence, the estimates indicate that educational improvements were
more likely among firms with pensions plans that covered larger
fractions of employees. Improvements in age-specific seminars were also
less common among larger firms and among unionized firms. There is
little if any relation between initial pension plan characteristics and
subsequent changes in educational offerings.
The pattern documented in Table 4 supports the hypothesis that, in
the context of 401(k)s, retirement seminars are remedial. These
offerings appear to be motivated by low participation among NHC
employees. This is consistent with the view that nondiscrimination
requirements provide a powerful impetus for the provision of retirement
education among 401(k) sponsors. However, it is doubtful that this is
the only motivation. If it were, then high initial HC participation
would also correlate with subsequent increases in education, which is
not the case. The small negative effect of initial HC participation
probably reflects the offsetting effects of two separate considerations:
first, that employers are inclined to offer education as a remedial
measure when 401(k) activity is low (regardless of HC or NHC status) and
second, that employers also use education to address binding
nondiscrimination constraints (which tend to arise when HC participation
is high). These findings are consistent with the indirect evidence on
selection offered by Bernheim and Garrett (2003).
IV. EVIDENCE ON PARTICIPATION IN AND CONTRIBUTIONS TO 401(K) PLANS
In this section, we use the KPMG Peat Marwick plan-level data to
examine factors associated with participation in and contributions to
401(k) plans. We use cross-sectional data on all the firms in our sample
and also examine changes for the same firm over 1993 and 1994. While we
focus on the role employer-based education plays in these decisions, we
examine several other plan and firm characteristics that may be related
to participation and contributions.
A. Factors Affecting Participation in Self-Directed Plans
The first step in our analysis of 401(k) activity is to examine
cross-sectional ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions of plan-level
participation rates. Since there are strong similarities between the
data for 1993 and 1994 and since we are not interested in investigating
any specific hypotheses about the differences between these years, we
pool the two surveys. We include a year dummy to account for any
systematic factors that might influence participation or contributions
differently through time. As in the previous section, pooling the data
raises one important empirical issue: since many of the same firms were
surveyed in both years, it is doubtful that the error terms are
independent across all observations. While OLS estimates are still
consistent under these conditions, the conventional method of computing standard errors is inapplicable. In our reported estimates, we again
correct our standard errors to reflect clustered sampling.
Since nondiscrimination rules are binding for many employers
(Garrett 1996), education programs may be designed to encourage
participation by NHC employees. Moreover, since HC and NHC households
start out with different levels of financial sophistication, we would
expect financial education to affect their behavior differently. For
both reasons, we estimate separate regressions for these groups as well
as for the combined sample.
Results are contained in the first panel of Table 5. The dependent
variables for these regressions--the plan participation rates-vary from
1% to 100%. The estimated effects of the key explanatory variables are
described below.
The role of seminars. For our base-case estimates, we use dummy
variables to measure the intensity (frequency) of educational offerings.
In this way, we avoid imposing assumptions on the functional relation
between participation and an arbitrarily scaled measure of education (as
discussed in Section II, we do, however, use the same dummy variable to
represent the responses sometimes and rarely). In the Robustness
subsection, we also present results based on a single scalar measure of
educational intensity. We also focus exclusively on seminars for all
employees rather than on seminars targeted at employees more than 50 yr
or employees near retirement. In practice, the seminar variables are
highly colinear, and it is difficult to identify their separate effects
with precision.
Reading across the first two rows of the first panel of Table 5, it
is apparent that frequent seminars have a consistently positive and
significant effect on participation in self-directed plans. For NHC
employees, frequent seminars are associated with participation rates
that are 11.5 percentage points higher than plans with no seminars. The
corresponding figure for HC employees is 6.4 percentage points. These
are economically large estimates given mean participation
rates--60%-80%--in the sample. The occasional seminar indicator variable
is, however, insignificant in each specification.
The results in Table 5 may obscure the relation between education
and participation among HC employees. Although censoring at the plan
level (at either 0% or 100%) is relatively rare for "all"
employees and for NHC employees, it is much more common for HC
employees. Specifically, for 32% of the sample, the HC participation
rate is 100%. Obviously, increases in seminars and changes in other plan
characteristics cannot be associated with higher participation rates for
companies that achieve 100% HC participation. We investigate the effects
of censoring in the Robustness subsection below where we estimate Tobit
specifications.
These results are consistent with the hypothesis that seminars
stimulate 401 (k) participation generally and especially among NHC
employees. This implies that retirement seminars may be an effective
response to nondiscrimination rules. However, there is no indication in
the pooled results that seminars matter unless they are conducted
frequently.
Other forms of education and information dissemination. We include
several additional education variables (newsletters and summary plan
descriptions) to examine whether all educational and informational
efforts are equally effective. Summary plan descriptions typically
amount to disclosure of plan characteristics and contain very little (if
any) recognizable education. While it is perhaps conceivable that
employees would be unwilling to trust (and therefore to participate in)
their pension plans without disclosure, we would nevertheless be
surprised if the use of these materials had a measurable effects on plan
activity. In contrast, newsletters often serve the same function as
seminars, but provide information through printed, rather that
audio-visual media. According to a survey by the Employee Benefit
Research Institute, 92% of 401(k) participants said that they read these
materials and 33% said that they contributed more to their plans as a
result. One might therefore expect newsletters to have an effect on
behavior similar to that of seminars. Alternatively, individuals may
exaggerate their responses to newsletters in response to survey
questions, particularly if they perceive this to be the
"appropriate response."
Notably, in the regressions of Table 5, aside from seminars, no
other medium of providing information and education to employees-either
through newsletters or summary plan descriptions--has any significant
association with participation rates. This is consistent with the
hypothesis that these media have no effect on participation. In
principle, selection bias could mask a behavioral response. However, in
contrast to seminars, there is little indication in the results of
Section III that the provision of written materials is motivated by low
participation.
Plan characteristics. There is mixed evidence in the literature on
the effect of matching rates on participation in self-directed plans,
despite the fact that matching is very common. According to a 1990
Hewitt and Associates survey, 79% of 944 major U.S. corporations matched
employee contributions. Papke (1995) finds a strong, positive
relationship between match rates and participation in cross-sectional
regressions using data from Form 5500.s The effect disappears in her
preferred, fixed effects specification. Andrews (1992) uses data from
the Current Population Survey and finds a positive relationship between
the presence of a match and the participation rates. Kusko, Poterba, and
Wilcox (1998) examine data from a single firm over several years, where
the match rate varied from 0% to 139% of employee contributions (up to
6% of salary). They found little variation in participation rates across
years, which lead them to conclude that their results suggest "a
relatively small elasticity of participation with respect to the match
rate, and cast substantial doubt on the view that employer matching is a
key factor in explaining the rapid expansion of 401(k) plans."
However, the 401(k) sponsored by the firm examined by Kusko, Poterba,
and Wilcox was part of a profit-sharing plan and, hence, had unusually
volatile match rates. It is not clear that one can generalize from
participation responses in profit-sharing plans to more common plan
types, where match rates change much less frequently. In principal, we
expect matching rates to exert a positive effect on participation since
they provide a pure substitution effect at the extensive margin.
In all the cross-sectional regressions we have examined, there is a
positive and significant correlation between the existence of a match
and participation. (9) The regression results in Table 5 imply that
plans with matches have participation rates that are 14.6-16.9
percentage points higher than plans without matches.
Loan provisions allow families to borrow against contributions made
to the self-directed plan. Conventional reasoning suggests that eligible
workers will be more likely to participate in plans with loan provisions
since they will have access to funds in the event they need to borrow.
An alternative view holds that loan provisions will be negatively
correlated with participation because they exacerbate
"self-control" problems with saving (e.g., Sheffrin and Thaler 1988). We find that the correlation between the existence of loan
provisions and participation are positive, but insignificant in the
regressions for all employees, and negative, but insignificant in the
separate regressions for HC or NHC employees.
Having a broad range of investment options presumably increases the
attractiveness of participation. The number of options in these plans is
not particularly large, with a mean of 2.8 in 1993 and a mean of 3.7 in
1994. A single investment option can be narrow (say stock in the
employee's company or a guaranteed life insurance contract), or
broad, like the Fidelity family of mutual funds. Although we expect
investment options to be positively correlated with participation, this
effect is not significant in any specification. Conceivably, this
finding may be attributable to the coarseness of our measure for the
number of options (e.g., the vast family of Fidelity equity mutual funds
would be considered one option).
Firm characteristics. An obvious concern with cross-sectional
estimates of the kind considered here is that the variables of interest
may be correlated with unobserved firm-specific characteristics. In that
case, the correlations that we attribute to seminars may in fact reflect
other factors. In addition to the plan characteristics already
mentioned, we therefore include a set of firm-specific variables to try
to account for other pertinent factors.
The existence of other pension plans should matter for two distinct
reasons. First, other pension plans may be positively correlated with
participation in a self-directed plan. There is extensive evidence that
the existence of a 401(k) is positively correlated with employees'
tastes for saving (Bernheim 1997; Engen, Gale, and Scholz 1994). It is
likely that the same is true for other pensions. Thus, the presence of
pensions may be positively correlated with participation in
self-directed plans. Second, other pension plans may reduce the
likelihood of participation in a self-directed plan because the pension
may provide households with sufficient retirement saving.
As would be expected if pensions and self-directed plans are
initiated in response to employees' wishes, participation rates are
higher in self-directed plans when the sponsoring firms offer at least
one other pension plan. The effect for all employees is significant at
conventional levels.
There may be systematic differences in self-directed plan offerings
depending on the size of the firm and on the number of employees covered
by the plan. These differences might, for example, arise from economies
of scale in plan administration or from correlations between size and
other variables, such as plan age, unobserved dimensions of plan
generosity, or the nature of peer group effects. We include the number
of employees in the firm to capture variations in participation that may
be associated with firm size, and the fraction of employees covered to
capture variations in participation that may be related to plan size. We
find that firm size is negatively associated with participation, but
that participation rises significantly with the fraction of employees
covered.
The unionization indicator variable is consistently insignificant
across specifications.
Summary. In pooled cross-sectional regressions, there are a number
of factors that are significantly associated with participation,
including match rates and certain characteristics of the company. The
effect of frequent seminars is economically large, positive, and
statistically significant. No other educational variable significantly
affects participation. In light of the selection issue documented in
Section III, there is reason to believe that these estimates understate the behavioral impact of retirement seminars but may accurately reflect
the impact of written materials.
B. Factors Related to Contributions in Self-Directed Plans
As indicated in Table 1, the survey collects information on average
contribution rates for plan participants. Multiplying the average
contribution rate times the participation rate gives the average
contribution rate across all eligibles. We use this as our dependent
variable to examine contributions. Because the data are aggregated
across plans, there is no obvious way to use information on the fraction
of non-participants and the conditional mean among participants
separately without making strong ad hoc assumptions on the data. Since
the conditional mean among participants is of limited intrinsic
interest, we therefore use the transformed contribution variable.
Obviously, our contributions variable may inherit some of the
properties of our participation variable. Even so, there is no
compelling reason to expect, a priori, that contributions will vary with
education in the same way as participation. To see why, consider the
following example. Suppose a firm's employees differ in their taste
for saving. Those with a high taste will participate in self-directed
plans when available and, due to the tax subsidy (and possibly employer
match), devote a relatively high fraction of salary to these plans.
Employees with low tastes for saving will choose not to contribute. Now
suppose frequent seminars induce employees with low tastes for saving to
contribute. If they contribute at low levels, the mean contribution,
conditional on participation, may actually fall, unless education also
encourages high savers to save even more. It is conceivable, however,
that education might actually reduce saving among those who would
otherwise put away "too much" relative to standard rules of
thumb. Thus, even the unconditional mean of the contribution rate might
fall with education.
As is clear from the second panel of Table 5, the frequent seminar
variable is positively and significantly associated with contributions
for the regressions involving all employees and NHC employees. The
effect is quite large. Mean (unconditional) contribution rates are
around 3.4% of salary, so the estimates imply that contributions are
nearly 20% larger in firms offering frequent seminars. This result is
consistent with the hypothesis that retirement education--and frequent
seminars in particular--positively affect the size of contributions to
self-directed plans.
In the specifications for all employees, both match rates and loan
provisions are positively and significantly associated with contribution
rates. Larger firms have lower contribution rates (the effect is
significant for HC employees). The larger the fraction of employees
covered by a self-directed plan, the higher are contribution rates (the
effect is significant for NHC employees and all the employees
specifications).
C. Longitudinal Evidence on Participation and Contributions
The specifications shown in Table 5 use pooled data from 1993 to
1994. To control for spurious factors that might generate an apparent
cross-sectional relationship between seminars and participation or
contributions, we included a number of plan- and firm-specific
variables. Nevertheless, a skeptical reader might question these results
on the grounds that seminars are correlated with other firm-specific
characteristics, such as the degree of interest management takes in
their employees, and that these other characteristics are responsible
for the observed correlation with behavior (perhaps through plan
generosity, which is only imperfectly accounted for in our
specification).
As discussed earlier, we have observations in both years for nearly
300 firms. Thus, it is possible to repeat our analysis, differencing the
data for our short (2 yr) panel. While differencing removes
time-invariant plan-specific characteristics, it also exacerbates any
measurement error problems that might be present, making it more
difficult to estimate correlations that arise from behavioral
relationships.
The first panel of Table 6 examines participation, repeating the
same specifications as shown in Table 5 but using the first-differenced
data. Although the statistical significance of the results is not quite
as striking, this is probably to be expected because the sample size is
considerably smaller and because of the problems arising from
differencing short panels. Nevertheless, we find that instituting
seminars on a frequent basis is associated with a 7.7 percentage point
increase in participation rates, and the effect is significant at the
11% level for the all-employee sample. For NHC employees, the effect is
12.1 percentage points, and it is significant at the 7% level. It is
worth noting that the estimated effects of occasional seminars appear
stronger in the differenced estimates. Indeed, the effects of frequent
and occasional seminars now appear to be roughly proportional.
We view this as further support for the hypothesis that retirement
education--and frequent seminars in particular--influences the saving
behavior of employees. Naturally, we cannot resolve the question of
causality with only 2 yr of data; it is, for example, conceivable that
employees might agitate for seminars once they start participating
(though it is doubtful that their employer would respond over such a
short time frame).
Our results on match rates follow the pattern observed in the
literature. Although we find that match rates appear to have a strong,
positive correlation with participation and contributions in
cross-sectional data, the effect disappears when one follows the same
firms over time. Because actual changes in match rates are infrequent,
it is possible that "observed" changes are dominated by
measurement errors in which case the panel estimates of the matching
effect may be highly misleading. Satisfactory resolution of the role
played by matching on participation in self-directed plans requires
better data. In general, very few other variables are significant in the
participation rate specifications (and none are significant in the HC
group). (10)
The second panel of Table 6 examines contributions, repeating the
same specifications as shown in Table 5 but using the first-differenced
data. The frequent seminar variable is again significant for the NHC
group, and it is marginally significant in the specifications for all
employees. The only other significant coefficients (at conventional
levels) are the occasional seminar variable (for HC employees) and the
unionization variable (for all employees and HC employees).
D. Robustness
The results presented in the previous sections depict a strong
correlation between frequent seminars and 401(k) activity, especially
among NHC employees. To verify the robustness of these results, we
examine the sensitivity of our results to a different method for
measuring the intensity of education. We also employ several alternate
estimation techniques: median, robust, and Tobit regression.
In the previous section, there were certain cases (most notably
differenced specifications for participation) where the effects of
frequent seminars were only marginally significant. This may occur, at
least in part, because we are asking the data to identify too many
parameters. In these same cases, the point estimates for the effects of
occasional seminars are roughly half the corresponding point estimates
for the effects of frequent seminars (Table 6). It is therefore natural
to consider an alternate specification based on a scalar measure of
educational intensity that allows us to summarize the effects of
education through a single parameter. Instead of constructing dummy
variables based on the frequency of educational offerings, we simply
measure frequency on a scale of 0 to 3, depending on whether education
is offered never, rarely, sometimes, or often. This specification forces
the effects of an increase in the frequency of education to be the same
when moving from each qualitative response to the next. That is, it
assumes that an increase from never to rarely has the same effect on
participation and contribution rates as an increase from rarely to
sometimes or sometimes to often. While restrictive, it is more
parsimonious than our original procedure and is generally not rejected
by the data.
We estimate median and robust regression models to reduce the
potential influence of outlying observations. (11) The standard errors
reported for the median and robust regressions (as well as for the Tobit
estimates) using the pooled data are not adjusted for the fact that the
same firm may appear in the pooled sample twice. As the standard errors
were similar with and without this correction in the OLS specifications
shown in Table 5, we do not view this as a major shortcoming.
We use Tobit regressions to account for right and left censoring of
participation rates at 0% and 100%. While censoring occurs in the data
for all three employee categories, it is particularly prevalent for HC
employees. In the pooled data, the participation rate equals 100% for
all employees in 29 of 1,027 observations and for NHC employees in 27 of
805 observations. For HC employees, this number jumps to 267 of 824
observations or approximately 30% of the sample. Left-censored
observation (i.e., those for which the participation rate is 0%) are not
nearly as prevalent. There are no such observations for all employees
and NHC employees and only 12 cases for HC employees. We estimate Tobit
models only for participation rates using pooled cross-sectional data.
While censoring is also present in the differenced versions of these
models as well as in models for contribution rates (both because of the
censoring of participation and because of limits on contributions), the
Tobit model is inappropriate in these contexts.
We report the coefficients of the seminar variables for these
alternate specifications in Tables 7 and 8. We omit the coefficients of
other explanatory variables to conserve space. Each of these
specifications employs the same additional covariates as the earlier OLS
regressions; results for these other covariates are similar to those
reported in previous subsections and are available on request.
An alternative measure of seminar intensity. For every
specification contained in Tables 58, we present results based on an
analogous specification in which we use a single scalar measure of
educational intensity, as described at the outset of this section. The
resulting coefficients for seminars are presented in Tables 7 and 8
under columns labeled "Intensity."
Generally speaking, for specifications involving pooled (as opposed
to differenced) data, the magnitudes and statistical precision of
educational effects are similar to the results obtained using separate
dummies for frequent and occasional seminars. However, the use of the
seminar intensity variable sharpens the estimates considerably for the
differenced data. For example, in the first column of Table 6 (which
concerns participation rates), the coefficient on frequent seminars for
NHC employees is only significant at the 7% level. However, its
magnitude is also roughly twice that of the occasional seminar variable,
which suggests that use of the intensity variable may be appropriate.
Indeed, as indicated in the first column of Table 7, the estimated
coefficient for the intensity variable in an analogous specification is
statistically significant at the 1% level. A similar observation applies
to differenced estimates of participation rates for all employees. In
general, with differenced data, the effects of seminars on participation
(Table 7) and contributions (Table 8) are found to be significant at a
higher level of confidence when a single measure of educational
intensity is used.
Median and robust regressions: robustness of participation results.
We present median and robust regression results for participation in the
middle sections of Table 7. In many respects, these results are
qualitatively similar to the OLS estimates. In the pooled data, the
coefficient on frequent seminars for NHC employees drops from 11.5 in
the OLS specification to 9.9 in the median and 11.2 in the robust
regressions. However, both these coefficients remain significant at the
1% level. The coefficients of occasional seminars for NHC employees rise
relative to OLS but still fail to achieve statistical significance at
conventional levels. There is no indication that seminars--even frequent
ones--have a significant impact on the participation rates of HC
employees. It is therefore possible that the effects of frequent
seminars on HC employees measured in OLS regressions (as well as in the
Tobit regressions reported later) reflect the influence of outliers. For
HC employees, the unexpected negative coefficient (from OLS) on
occasional seminars is reduced to a number much closer to 0 in both the
median and robust regressions. Finally, the effect of frequent seminars
on participation rates for all employees is a bit weaker in median
regression and robust regressions than for OLS; however, the effect of
occasional seminars, though still smaller than the effect of frequent
seminars, now achieves conventional levels of statistical significance.
For the differenced data, both the median and the robust
regressions reduce the size of the coefficients for frequent seminars
but also increase the precision with which they are measured. The
coefficient on frequent seminars for NHC employees drops from 12.1 in
the OLS specification to 7.4 in the median and 8.6 in the robust
regressions. However, while the OLS coefficient was only significant at
the 7% level, the median regression coefficient is significant at the 2%
level and the robust regression at the 5% level. Notably, while the
effect of occasional seminars on NHC participation was not significant
in OLS estimates with differenced data, it is significant (and
substantial) in both median and robust regression estimates. Median and
robust regressions also yield more precise coefficients for HC
employees. For the median regression, in particular, the effect is
statistically significant even though its magnitude is small. We suspect
that this result is attributable to the nature of the distribution of
the differenced HC participation rates. Many of the participation rates
for HC employees are at or near 100% for both 1993 and 1994;
consequently, more than 30% of the firms in the sample experience no
change in the measured participation rate of HC employees between 1993
and 1994. Since the median change is zero, and since there are so many
zeros, it is not surprising that our explanatory variables are found to
have very little effect on the median or that this finding is precise.
The effect of frequent seminars on participation rates disappears in the
median and robust regression estimates of the differenced specification
for all employees; however, the impact of occasional seminars emerges as
significant. Finally, as noted earlier, the use of the intensity
variable also enhances the statistical significance of the educational
effect on NHC participation rates in both the median and the robust
regression estimates that make use of differenced data.
Median and robust regressions: robustness of the contribution
results. The median and robust regression results for contribution rates
are shown in Table 8. The top panel contains results for regressions
with pooled data. The results for the robust regressions are
qualitatively similar to the earlier OLS estimation, with a slight drop
in the coefficients on frequent seminars. For example, in the
specification for NHC employees, this coefficient drops from 0.81 to
0.69. The statistical significance of the estimates is comparable to
that of the OLS coefficients, with the coefficient on frequent seminars
for NHC employees remaining significant at the 1% significance level.
The effect of occasional seminars is also statistically significant in
the specification for all employees. In contrast, the median regression
results for contribution rates are weaker than the OLS and robust
regression results. While the signs of the coefficients are the same,
magnitudes are generally lower and no single seminar dummy achieves
statistical significance at conventional levels. However, the seminar
intensity variables approach statistical significance at the 95%
confidence level in the specifications for NHC and all employees.
The bottom panel of Table 8 presents median and robust regression
results for contribution rates using differenced data. The effect of
frequent seminars on NHC contribution rates is still reasonably strong
and similar to that obtained using OLS. None of the other seminar
dummies depicted in this lower panel achieves statistical significance.
The estimated effect of frequent seminars on the HC contribution rate is
actually negative and fairly large in magnitude but not very precise.
However, as with the previous specifications, when the seminar intensity
variable is used, median and robust regression estimates of the seminar
effect for NHC employees are similar in magnitude to the OLS results and
statistically significant at the usual levels of confidence.
Tobit regression results. Tobit results for rates of participation
are shown in the last section of Table 7. The coefficients for both
frequent and occasional seminars increase in size (relative to OLS) for
all three employee groups. The most dramatic change occurs in the
coefficient for frequent seminars for HC employees, which increases from
6.4 to 10.5. This result is not surprising given the fact that more than
30% of the HC observations are right censored. Although precision is
somewhat lower for the Tobit estimates than for OLS, the coefficient of
frequent seminars for NHC employees remains significant at the 1% level
and the coefficient for HC employees remains significant at the 5%
level. These results suggest that censoring causes a downward bias in
the OLS coefficients and that HC and NHC employees respond to education
more similarly than the OLS results appear to indicate. Again, using the
seminar intensity variable results in more precisely estimated effects.
V. CONCLUSIONS
In this article, we have examined the effects of employer-based
retirement education on 401(k) activity using firm-level data. Our
results indicate that retirement seminars are generally associated with
significantly higher rates of participation and contributions, at least
when the frequency of these offerings is high. The effect appears to be
particularly strong for NHC employees. Our findings reflect both
cross-sectional and longitudinal patterns in the data, and they are
robust with respect to a variety of estimation techniques.
The current article is complementary to Bernheim and Garrett (1996,
2003) who use household survey data to investigate the effects of
education on total saving both inside and outside of pension plans.
However, since their data are cross-sectional, they are forced to make
indirect inferences concerning the probable direction of biases that
might result from the inevitable failure to control for unobserved
individual effects. With household survey data, it is also difficult to
distinguish between the effects of education on behavior and the effects
of education on the way that individuals report behavior. In contrast,
the employer survey data used here allow us to examine both
cross-sectional and longitudinal patterns; moreover, there is relatively
little risk that the education of employees would affect the way that
employers report rates of participation and contributions. The tradeoff,
of course, is that employer survey data provide no information on assets
held outside of pension plans and therefore do not permit us to
investigate whether increased participation and contributions reflect
new saving rather than asset reshuffling.
Taken together, the current article and that of Bernheim and
Garrett (1996, 2003) suggest that financial education in the workplace
can exert a strong influence on personal financial decisions. More
generally, these studies, along with others that followed them, raise
the possibility that the enhancement of decisionmaking skills (as
opposed to labor market skills) may constitute a significant economic
return to education.
REFERENCES
A. Foster Higgins & Co., Inc. Survey of Employee Savings Plans,
1994, Report 2: Plan Participation and Discrimination Testing.
Princeton, NJ: A. Foster Higgins & Co., Inc., 1994.
Andrews, E. S. "The Growth and Distribution of 401(k)
Plans," in Trends in Pensions 1992, edited by J. Turner and D.
Beller. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Labor, 1992, 149-76.
Bayer, P. J., B. D. Bernheim, and J. K. Scholz. "The Effects
of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of
Employers." NBER Working Paper No. 5655, 1996.
Bernheim, B. D. "Social Security Benefits: An Empirical Study
of Expectations and Realizations," in Issues in Contemporary
Retirement, edited by E. Lazear and R. Ricardo-Campbell. Stanford, CA:
Hoover Institution Press, 1988, 312-45.
--. "The Timing of Retirement: A Comparison of Expectations
and Realizations," in The Economics of Aging, edited by D. Wise.
Chicago: NBER University of Chicago Press, 1989, 335-55.
--. "Personal Saving, Information, and Economic Literacy: New
Directions for Public Policy," in Tax Policy for Economic Growth in
the 1990s, edited by C. E. Walker, M. A. Bloomfield, and M. Fleming.
Washington, DC: American Council for Capital Formation, 1994, 53-78.
--. "Do Households Appreciate Their Financial Vulnerabilities?
An Analysis of Actions, Perceptions, and Public Policy," in Tax
Policy and Economic Growth, edited by C. E. Walker, M. A. Bloomfield,
and M. Fleming. Washington, DC: American Council for Capital Formation,
1995, 1-30.
--. "Rethinking Saving Incentives," in Fiscal Policy:
Lessons From Economic Research, edited by A. Auerbach. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press, 1997, 259-311.
--. "Financial Illiteracy, Education, and Retirement
Saving," in Living with Defined Contribution Pensions, edited by O.
S. Mitchell and S. J. Schieber. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania
Press, Pension Research Council, The Wharton School, University of
Pennsylvania, 1998, 38-68.
Bernheim, B. D., and D. M. Garrett. "The Determinants and
Consequences of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a
Survey of Households." NBER Working Paper No. 5667, 1996.
--. "The Effects of Financial Education in the Workplace:
Evidence from a Survey of Households." Journal of Public Economies
87, 2003, 1487-1519.
Bernheim, B. D., D. M. Garrett, and D. Maki. "The Long-Term
Effects of High School Financial Curriculum Mandates." NBER Working
Paper No. 6085, 1997.
--. "The Long-Term Effects of High School Financial Curriculum
Mandates." Journal of Public Economics, 2001, 435-65.
Bernheim, B. D., and J. K. Scholz. "Private Saving and Public
Policy." Tax Policy and the Economy, 7, 1993, 73-110.
Beshears, J., J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B. C. Madrian. "The
Impact of Employer Matching on Savings Plan Participation under
Automatic Enrollment." NBER Working Paper No. 13352, 2007.
Borleis, M. W., and K. K. Wedell. "How to Spark Employee
Interest with Employer Matching Contributions." Profit Sharing,
1994, 7-16.
Card, D. "Earnings, Schooling, and Ability Revisited."
Research in Labor Economics, 14, 1995, 23-48.
Choi, J. J., D. Laibson, and B. C. Madrian. "Plan Design and
401(k) Savings Outcomes." National Tax Journal, 57, Part 1, 2004,
275-98.
Clancy, M., M. Grinstein-Weiss, and M. Schreiner, "Financial
Education and Savings Outcomes in Individual Development Accounts."
Working Paper No. 01-2, Center for Social Development, St. Louis:
Washington University of St. Louis, 2001.
Clark, R., and M. D'Ambrosio. "Ignorance is Not Bliss:
The Importance of Financial Education." Research Dialogue 78.
Washington, DC: TIAA-CREF Institute, 2003.
--. Forthcoming. "Adjusting Retirement Goals and Saving
Behavior: The Role of Financial Education," in Overcoming the
Saving Slump: How to Increase the Effectiveness of Financial Education
and Saving Programs, edited by A. Lusardi, Mimeo. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 2007.
Clark, R., and S. J. Schieber. "Factors Affecting
Participation Rate and Contribution Levels in 401(k) Plans." in
Living with Defined Contribution Pensions, edited by O. S. Mitchell and
S. J. Schieber. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, Pension
Research Council, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 1998.
Cole, S., and G. K. Shastry. "If You Are So Smart, Why
Aren't You Rich? The Effects of Education, Financial Literacy, and
Cognitive Ability on Financial Market Participation." Mimeo,
Harvard University, 2007.
Courchane, M., and P. Zorn. "Consumer Literacy and
Creditworthiness." Mimeo, Freddie Mac, 2005.
Dynan, K. E., J. Skinner, and S. P. Zeldes. "Do the Rich Save
More?" Journal of Political Economy, 112, 2004, 397-444.
Duflo, E., and E. Saez. "The Role of Information and Social
Interactions in Retirement Plan Decisions: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 2003, 815-42.
Employee Benefit Research Institute. Retirement Confidence in
America: Getting Ready for Tomorrow. Washington, DC: Employment Benefit
Research Institute EBRI Special Report SR-27, Issue Brief No. 156, 1994.
Employee Benefit Research Institute. Can We Save Enough to Retire?
Participant Education in Defined Contribution Plans." Washington,
DC: Employment Benefit Research Institute EBRI Issue Brief no. 160,
1995.
Engen, E. M., W. G. Gale, and J. K. Scholz. "Do Saving
Incentives Work?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 1994,
85-151.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. A Longitudinal Evaluation of
the Immediate-term Impact of Money-Smart Financial Education Curriculum
upon Consumers' Behavior and Confidence. Washington, DC: Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, 2007.
Garrett, D. M. "Public and Private Retirement Programs in the
United States." Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1996.
Geisel, J. "Communication Yields Success for XTRA 401(k)." Business Insurance, 10, 1995, 3.
Gustman, A., and T. Steinmeier. "Imperfect Knowledge,
Retirement and Saving." NBER Working Paper No. 8406, 2001.
Hilgert, M. A., J. M. Hogarth, and S. G. Beverly, "Household
Financial Management: The Connection Between Knowledge and
Behavior." Federal Reserve Bulletin, 89, 2003, 309-322.
Hira, T. K., and C. Loibla. "Understanding the Impact of
Employer-Provided Financial Education on Workplace Satisfaction."
Journal of Consumer Affairs, 39, 2005, 173-94.
Hogarth, J. M., and M. A. Hilgert. "Financial Knowledge,
Experience and Learning Preferences: Preliminary Results from a New
Survey on Financial Literacy." Consumer Interests Annual, 48, 2002.
Kusko. A., J. M. Poterba, and D. W. Wilcox. "Employee
Decisions With Respect to 401(k) Plans," in Living with Defined
Contribution Pensions, edited by O. S. Mitchell and S. Scheiber.
Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, Pension Research
Council, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 1998, 98-112.
Lusardi, A. "Information, Expectations, and Savings for
Retirement," in Behavioral Dimensions of Retirement Economics,
edited by H. Aaron. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution and Russell
Sage Foundation, 1999, 81-115.
--. "Saving for Retirement: The Importance of Planning."
Research Dialogue 66, Washington, DC: TIAA-CREF Institute, 2000.
--. "Savings and the Effectiveness of Financial
Education," in Pension Design and Structure: New Lessons from
Behavioral Finance, edited by O. S. Mitchell and S. Utkus. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2004, 157-84.
Lusardi, A., and O. S. Mitchell. "Baby Boomer Retirement
Security: The Roles of Planning, Financial Literacy, and Housing
Wealth." Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 2007, 205-24.
Madrian, B. C., and D. F. Shea. "The Power of Suggestion:
Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior." Quarterly
Journal of Economies, 116, 2001, 1149-87.
Maki, D. "Financial Education and Private Pensions," in
Private Pensions and Public Policies, edited by W. Gale, J. Shoven, and
M. Warshowsky. Brookings Institution Press, 2004, 126-39.
Mandell, L. Financial Literacy: Improving Education-Results of the
2006 National JumpStart Survey. Washington, DC: Jumpstart Coalition,
2006.
--. Forthcoming. "Financial Education in High School," in
Overcoming the Saving Slump: How to Increase the Effectiveness of
Financial Education and Saving Programs, edited by A. Lusardi. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 2007.
Martin. M. "A Literature Review of the Effectiveness of
Financial Education." Working Paper No. P 07-3, Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, 2007.
Mincer, J. "Investment in Human Capital and Personal Income
Distribution." Journal of Political Economy, 66, 1958, 281-302.
Muller, L. A. "Does Retirement Education Teach People to Save
Pension Distributions?" Social Security Bulletin, 64, 2001-2002,
48-65.
Papke, L. E., "Participation in and Contributions to 401(k)
Plans: Evidence from Plan Data." Journal of Human Resources, 30,
1995, 311-25.
Papke, L., M. Petersen, and J. M. Poterba. "Did 401(k) Plans
Replace Other Employer Provided Pensions?" in Advances in the
Economics of Aging, edited by D. Wise. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1996, 219-36.
Poterba, J. M., S. F. Venti, and D. A. Wise. "401(k) Plans and
Tax-Deferred Saving," in Studies in the Economies of Aging, edited
by David A. Wise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994, 105-38.
Scott, J. "Determining the Size and Distribution of 401(k) Tax
Benefits: An Empirical Application of Real Options Pricing Theory."
Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1997.
Sheffrin, H. M., and R. H. Thaler. "The Behavioral Life-Cycle
Hypothesis." Economic Inquiry. 26, 1988, 609-43.
Sherraden, M., and R. Boshara. Forthcoming. "Learning from
Individual Development Accounts," in Overcoming the Saving Slump:
How to Increase the Effectiveness of Financial Education and Saving
Programs, edited by A. Lusardi. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
2007.
Sunden, A. "How Much Do People Need to Know about Their
Pensions and What Do They Know?" in Pension Reform: Issues and
Prospects for Non-Financial Defined Contribution (NDC) Schemes, edited
by R. Holzmann and E. Palmer. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications,
2006, 325-41.
Tennyson, S., and C. Nguyen. "State Curriculum Mandates and
Student Knowledge of Personal Finance." Journal of Consumer
Affairs, 35, 2001, 241-62.
ABBREVIATIONS
HC: Highly Compensated
NHC: Nonhighly Compensated
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2008.00156.x
(1.) "Employees Getting More: Investment Education, Planning
Help on the Increase." Pensions and Investments, 23, 1995, 74.
(2.) We originally intended to supplement the evidence in this
article with an analysis of a second data set. As an unfortunate and
unintended consequence of this worthy (though in hindsight, plainly
misguided) intention, the article lay mostly dormant for a dozen years
during which our intermittent efforts ultimately led us to the
conclusion that the new data were insufficiently rich to yield
meaningful results. Though other studies of financial education in the
workplace have been written and published during the intervening years,
this article continues to make a distinctive contribution, in that our
data offer detail on the content of educational offerings, as well as
longitudinal information for a reasonably large and diverse group of
firms.
(3.) Since the data were provided to us without firm identifiers,
we were limited to information collected by the survey.
(4.) The results in this article do not change qualitatively when
we use other groupings of the responses to these questions. To verify
the robustness of our results and to reduce still further the number of
parameters, we also occasionally define a single variable measuring the
intensity of the educational offering. The variable is set equal to 3 if
the device is used often, 2 if it is sometimes used, 1 if it is rarely
used, and 0 if it is never used.
(5.) The survey also provides information about other potentially
useful plan features, such as hardship withdrawals and the actual
matching rate provided by the firm. Unfortunately, the usefulness of
these variables is diminished by data limitations and we therefore do
not include them in our specifications. For example, in each year of the
survey, more than 94% of employers allow hardship withdrawals, so that
there is not enough variation in the data to examine their effect on
plan activity. Also, fewer than 40% of the employers who offer an
employer match report the actual matching rate. Therefore, incorporating
the actual rate into our specifications would severely limit the sample
size available for estimation.
(6.) While the survey asks for the average contribution as a
percentage of compensation, it is not completely clear from the wording
whether it means the average over contributors or the average over
eligibles. The designers of the survey suggest that the former is the
natural interpretation. Given the data, this interpretation appears to
be correct. We calculated the average contribution for companies that
reported participation rates from 0% to 25%, 25% to 50%, 50% to 75%, and
75% to 100%. There was no evidence of systematic variation in
contributions over these categories. If companies were reporting the
average over eligibles, then the average would (as a purely mechanical
matter) have to rise steeply across these categories.
(7.) Unfortunately, this variable is not available for defined
benefit plans and therefore could not be included in the regressions of
Table 2.
(8.) Form 5500 is filed annually with the Internal Revenue Service
by all sponsors of pension plans with more than 100 participants. The
data include plan eligibility, participation, employment, administrative
cost, distributions, and contributions.
(9.) Recall from Section II that data on the level of match are
missing for a large number of observations, so we use only an indicator
variable for whether the firm offers a match.
(10.) In Table 6, the occasional provision of summary plan
descriptions appears to have a positive and significant effect on
participation. However, this result is apparently driven by outliers; it
vanishes when more robust estimation techniques are applied (as in the
next section).
(11.) Median regression accomplishes this by minimizing the sum of
the absolute values of the residuals rather than the sum of squared
residuals. Robust regression first eliminates gross outliers and then
performs Huber iterations followed by biweight iterations to weight
observations more evenly in the loss function.
PATRICK J. BAYER, B. DOUGLAS BERNHEIM, and JOHN KARL SCHOLZ *
* We are grateful to the National Science Foundation (Grant No.
SBR94-09043 and Grant No. SBR95-11321) as well as to Merrill Lynch,
Inc., for financial support. We would also like to thank KPMG Peat
Marwick LLP and, in particular, Martha Priddy Patterson for making
available the data used to conduct this study.
Bayer: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Duke
University, Box 90097, Durham, NC 27708. Phone 919-660-1832; Fax
919-684-8974; E-mail patrick.
[email protected]
Bernheim: Professor, Department of Economics, Stanford University,
Stanford, CA 94305-6072. Phone 650-725-8732; Fax: 650-725-5702; E-mail
bernheim@stanford. edu
Scholz: Professor, Department of Economics, University of
Wisconsin--Madison, 1180 Observatory Drive; Madison, Wisconsin 53706-1393. Phone 608-2625380; Fax 608-265-3119; E-mail:
[email protected]
TABLE 1 Mean and Median 401(k) Participation and Contribution Rates
Observations Median
1993
Participation rates NHC 415 60.9
HC 422 92.5
All 530 70.0
Conditional contribution NHC 395 5.0
rates HC 398 6.0
All 457 5.0
Unconditional contribution NHC 349 2.8
rates HC 352 5.7
All 437 3.4
1994
Participation rates NHC 392 60.0
HC 404 92.0
All 500 70.0
Conditional contribution NHC 357 5.0
rates HC 359 6.0
All 412 5.0
Unconditional contribution NHC 311 2.6
rates HC 317 5.4
All 393 3.3
Employment-
Mean Weighted Mean
1993
Participation rates NHC 59.44 59.66
HC 82.59 82.34
All 63.08 64.32
Conditional contribution NHC 4.96 4.72
rates HC 6.75 6.09
All 5.15 5.14
Unconditional contribution NHC 3.06 2.91
rates HC 5.79 5.16
All 3.39 3.46
1994
Participation rates NHC 57.68 55.18
HC 78.56 82.69
All 61.23 60.77
Conditional contribution NHC 4.86 4.84
rates HC 6.66 6.05
All 5.34 5.32
Unconditional contribution NHC 2.94 2.79
rates HC 5.44 5.07
All 3.41 3.55
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits
in the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 2
The Effect of Retirement Plan Type on Education--All Companies
Dependent Variable
Seminars for
Seminars for Employees
All Employees More Than 50 Yr
Only 401(k) plan 0.251 (0.129) -0.221 (0.141)
Only 403(b) plan 0.759 (0.204) 0.503 (0.205)
Only another plan 0.107 (0.151) -0.177 (0.165)
Two or more plans 0.326 (0.113) 0.340 (0.119)
Total employment (a) 0.255 (0.181) 0.352 (0.141)
Fraction of employees 0.003 (0.0012) 0.005 (0.0012)
covered by plans
1994 dummy 0.093 (0.060) -0.050 (0.063)
Intercept -0.647 (0.142) -0.999 (0.151)
N 1778 1773
Dependent Variable
Seminars for
Employees Summary Plan
Near Retirement Descriptions
Only 401(k) plan -0.343 (0.143) 0.727 (0.134)
Only 403(b) plan 0.325 (0.207) 0.185 (0.202)
Only another plan -0.092 (0.162) 0.059 (0.148)
Two or more plans 0.274 (0.119) 0.554 (0.112)
Total employment (a) 0.322 (0.141) -0.174 (0.169)
Fraction of employees 0.004 (0.0012) -0.003 (0.0013)
covered by plans
1994 dummy 0.003 (0.064) -0.134 (0.065)
Intercept -0.951 (0.151) 0.431 (0.145)
N 1773 1771
Dependent Variable
Newsletters or
Periodicals
Only 401(k) plan 0.464 (0.129)
Only 403(b) plan 0.104 (0.200)
Only another plan -0.210 (0.148)
Two or more plans 0.484 (0.111)
Total employment (a) 0.204 (0.147)
Fraction of employees 0.000 (0.0012)
covered by plans
1994 dummy 0.077 (0.063)
Intercept 0.016 (0.141)
N 1778
Notes: Excluded variable is only defined benefits plan. Standard
errors are given in parentheses.
(a) Coefficients for total employment are multiplied by 105.
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in
the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 3
The Effect of Retirement Plan Type on Education--Companies
with 401(k) Plans
Dependent Variable
Seminars for
Seminars for All Employees
Employees More Than 50 Yr
Defined benefits plan 0.065 (0.106) 0.627 (0.115)
Other retirement plan, no -0.009 (0.109) 0.258 (0.120)
defined benefits plan
Total employment (a) 0.491 (0.264) 0.754 (0.292)
Fraction of employees 0.0019 (0.0016) 0.0034 (0.0017)
covered by plans
Union eligibility -0.038 (0.093) 0.016 (0.095)
Employer match -0.165 (O.111) -0.042 (0.111)
Number of options 0.166 (0.036) 0.179 (0.039)
Loans permitted 0.213 (0.090) 0.147 (0.095)
1994 dummy -0.015 (0.072) -0.216 (0.0801
Intercept -0.773 (0.173) -1.729 (0.188)
N 1,170 1,169
Dependent Variable
Seminars for
Employees Summary Plan
Near Retirement Descriptions
Defined benefits plan 0.652 (0.118) -0.090 (0.116)
Other retirement plan, no 0.343 (0.121) -0.020 (0.118)
defined benefits plan
Total employment (a) 0.702 (0.285) -0.389 (0.267)
Fraction of employees -0.0029 (0.0017) -0.0049 (0.0017)
covered by plans
Union eligibility 0.034 (O.U96) 0.056 (0.095)
Employer match -0.123 (0.110) 0.203 (0.119)
Number of options 0.186 (0.040) 0.132 (0.041)
Loans permitted 0.120 (0.093) 0.013 (0.095)
1994 dummy -0.203 (0.080 -0.229 (0.084)
Intercept -1.724 (0.190 0.737 (0.188)
N 1,170 1,162
Dependent Variable
Newsletters or
Periodicals
Defined benefits plan 0.072 (0.111)
Other retirement plan, no 0.082 (0.113)
defined benefits plan
Total employment (a) 0.397 (0.332)
Fraction of employees -0.0017 (0.0016)
covered by plans
Union eligibility 0.140 (0.096)
Employer match 0.054 (0.111)
Number of options 0.179 (0.038)
Loans permitted -0.034 (0.091)
1994 dummy -0.026 (0.081)
Intercept 0.044 (0.176)
N 1,169
Notes: Excluded variable is only 401(k) plan. Standard errors are
given in parentheses.
(a) Coefficients for total employment are multiplied by
[10.sup.5]; coefficients for 1994 dummy are multiplied by
[10.sup.4].
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in
the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 4
Predictors of Changes in Education
Dependent Variable
Seminars for
Seminars for Employees
All Employees More Than 50 Yr
NHC participation 1993 -0.0084 (0.0038) -0.0058 (0.0031)
HC participation 1993 -0.0018 (0.0035) -0.0045 (0.0028)
Fraction of employees 0.0044 (0.0030) 0.0031 (0.0024)
covered by plan
Total employment (a) 1993 0.091 (0.504) -0.959 (0.406)
Union eligibility 1993 -0.083 (0.182) -0.282 (0.148)
Employer match 1993 0.207 (0.227) -0.058 (0.182)
Defined benefits plan--1993 -0.339 (0.197) -0.082 (0.159)
Other pension plan, no defined -0.094 (0.208) -0.184 (0.167)
benefits plan--1993
Loans permitted 1993 0.059 (0.169) -0.144 (0.136)
Investment options 1993 0.058 (0.070) 0.071 (0.057)
Intercept 0.168 (0.416) 0.579 (0.344)
N 244 243
Dependent Variable
Seminars for
Employees Summary Plan
Near Retirement Descriptions
NHC participation 1993 -0.0059 (0.0032) -0.0013 (0.0047)
HC participation 1993 -0.0001 (0.0029) -0.0043 (0.0044)
Fraction of employees 0.0012 (0.0025) 0.0041 (0.0038)
covered by plan
Total employment (a) 1993 -0.448 (0.420) -0.338 (0.621)
Union eligibility 1993 -0.196 (0.152) -0.501 (0.224)
Employer match 1993 -0.030 (0.189) 0.251 (0.280)
Defined benefits plan--1993 -0.069 (0.164) -0.183 (0.243)
Other pension plan, no defined -0.069 (0.173) 0.107 (0.256)
benefits plan--1993
Loans permitted 1993 -0.005 (0.141) -0.015 (0.209)
Investment options 1993 0.027 (0.059) 0.003 (0.087)
Intercept 0.201 (0.346) -0.049 (0.519)
N 244 243
Dependent Variable
Newsletters or
Periodicals
NHC participation 1993 0.0020 (0.0046)
HC participation 1993 -0.0057 (0.0046)
Fraction of employees 0.0004 (0.0037)
covered by plan
Total employment (a) 1993 0.165 (0.609)
Union eligibility 1993 -0.057 (0.220)
Employer match 1993 0.412 (0.274)
Defined benefits plan--1993 -0.285 (0.238)
Other pension plan, no defined -0.180 (0.251)
benefits plan--1993
Loans permitted 1993 -0.045 (0.204)
Investment options 1993 0.079 (0.085)
Intercept -0.013 (0.502)
N 244
Note: All dependent variables are first differenced. Standard
errors are given in parentheses.
(a) Coefficients for total employment are multiplied by 105.
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in
the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 5
OLS Results for Participation and Contribution Rates
Dependent Variable
Participation Rate
NHC HC All
Seminars often 11.52 (3.00) 6.37 (2.94) 8.17 (2.46)
Seminars sometimes 1.74 (2.07) -298 (2.37) 1.43 (1.75)
or rarely
Newsletters often -0.58 (2.72) 1.09 (3.00) -2.30 (2.23)
Newsletters -0.91 (2.63) 0.01 (2.81) -0.83 (2.12)
sometimes or
rarely
Plan descriptions 0.35 (2.79) -1.66 (3.16) 2.17 (2.24)
often
Plan descriptions 2.16 (2.83) -1.00 (3.07) 1.98 (2.32)
sometimes or
rarely
Employer match 14.59 (2.55) 1694 (3.17) 17.27 (2.04)
Loans permitted -1.42 (2.09) -2.34 (2.20) 1.78 (1.74)
Investment options -0.158 (0.819) -0.237 (0.873) 0.712 (0.720)
Other pension plan 4.41 (2.36) 3.39 (2.53) 5.02 (2.06)
Total employment (a) -1.78 (0.64) -0.29 (0.66) -1.07 (0.53)
Fraction of 0.188 (0.039) 0.049 (0.042) 0.236 (0.034)
employees covered
by plan
Union eligibility 1.49 (2.09) 1.56 (2.19) 3.56 (1.72)
1994 dummy -2.30 (1.82) -4.41 (2.10) -3.24 (1.48)
Intercept 30.90 (4.47) 65.87 (5.09) 23.16 (3.64)
N 805 824 1,027
Dependent Variable
Contribution Rate
NHC HC All
Seminars often 0.809 (0.291) 0.342 (0.417) 0.677 (0.240)
Seminars sometimes 0.252 (0.171) 0.077 (0.261) 0.232 (0.142)
or rarely
Newsletters often 0.183 (0.211) 0.149 (0.380) -0.120 (0.186)
Newsletters -0.088 (0.210) -0.353 (0.350) -0.248 (0.183)
sometimes or
rarely
Plan descriptions -0.084 (0.196) 0.024 (0.366) -0.137 (0.182)
often
Plan descriptions 0.282 (0.220) -0274 (0.347) 0.007 (0.197)
sometimes or
rarely
Employer match 0.389 (0.238) 0.732 (0.413) 0.566 (0.205)
Loans permitted 0.076 (0.159) 0.003 (0.258) 0.313 (0.149)
Investment options 0.105 (0.066) 0.156 (0.107) 0.099 (0.062)
Other pension plan -0.203 (0.198) -0.306 (0.293) -0.035 (0.171)
Total employment (a) -0.91 (0.56) -1.71 (0.59) -0.45 (0.46)
Fraction of 0.0141 (0.0032) 0.0020 (0.0047) 0.0153 (0.0029)
employees covered
by plan
Union eligibility -0.045 (0.166) 0.320 (0.273) 0.171 (0.149)
1994 dummy -0.184 (0.145) -0.410 (0.239) -0.102 (0.124)
Intercept 1.313 (0.341) 4.870 (0.705) 1.386 (0.344)
N 658 667 827
Note: Huber standard errors are given in parentheses.
(a) Coefficients for total employment are multiplied by [10.sup.4] in
the participation specifications and 105 in the contribution
specifications.
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in the
1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 6
OLS Results for Changes in Participation and Contribution Rates
Dependent Variable
Participation Rate
NHC HC
Seminars often 12.14 (6.58) 6.60 (8.49)
Seminars sometimes 6.87 (4.53) 1.59 (5.97)
or rarely
Newsletters often -7.02 (5.35) -5.80 (7.01)
Newsletters sometimes -1.41 (4.85) -3.33 (6.30)
or rarely
Plan descriptions often 6.32 (5.30) 6.62 (6.69)
Plan descriptions 11.34 (5.49) 11.60 (6.97)
sometimes or rarely
Employer match -1.56 (5.66) 0.77 (7.61)
Loans permitted 1.31 (7.63) 1.30 (10.52)
Investment options 2.44 (1.89) 2.76 (2.50)
Other pension plan 9.44 (5.25) 5.02 (6.97)
Total employment (a) 0.43 (3.51) 2.25 (4.60)
Fraction of employees 0.135 (0.089) 0.098 (0.115)
covered by plan
Union eligibility -1.95 (4.92) 6.10 (6.28)
Intercept -7.81 (2.88) -8.55 (3.89)
N 188 196
Dependent Variable
Participation Contribution
Rate Rate
All NHC
Seminars often 7.65 (4.72) 1.106 (0.513)
Seminars sometimes 4.75 (3.19) 0.533 (0.344)
or rarely
Newsletters often -2.87 (3.93) -0.119 (0.410)
Newsletters sometimes -1.49 (3.65) -0.078 (0.384)
or rarely
Plan descriptions often 3.18 (3.76) 0.240 (0.411)
Plan descriptions 6.29 (3.80) 0.711 (0.424)
sometimes or rarely
Employer match -0.22 (4.36) -0.072 (0.457)
Loans permitted 2.54 (5.93) -0.683 (0.617)
Investment options 0.18 (1.43) 0.300 (0.153)
Other pension plan 3.51 (4.11) -0.002 (0.419)
Total employment (a) 1.54 (2.34) 0.083 (0.261)
Fraction of employees 0.078 (0.067) 0.0045 (0.0070)
covered by plan
Union eligibility 9.00 (3.82) 0.055 (0.402)
Intercept -4.38 (2.10) -0.360 (0.239)
N 291 148
Dependent Variable
Contribution Rate
HC All
Seminars often -0.141 (0.772) 0.408 (0.348)
Seminars sometimes 1.044 (0.540) 0.214 (0.235)
or rarely
Newsletters often -0.912 (0.624) -0.360 (0.292)
Newsletters sometimes -0.557 (0.572) -0.081 (0.279)
or rarely
Plan descriptions often 0.021 (0.597) -0.224 (0.272)
Plan descriptions 0.695 (0.624) 0.217 (0.278)
sometimes or rarely
Employer match 0.270 (0.695) -0.016 (0.325)
Loans permitted -0.715 (1.02) -0.603 (0.433)
Investment options 0.102 (0.226) 0.132 (0.107)
Other pension plan 0.408 (0.629) 0.037 (0.295)
Total employment (a) -0.011 (0.389) 0.030 (0.168)
Fraction of employees 0.0131 (0.0108) -0.0041 (0.0049)
covered by plan
Union eligibility 1.465 (0.586) 0.786 (0.272)
Intercept -0.557 (0.359) -0.213 (0.165)
N 147 213
Notes: All variables, both dependent and independent, are first
differenced. Standard errors are given in parentheses.
(a) Coefficients for total employment are multiplied by
[10.sup.4].
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in
the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 7
Robustness of Participation Results
OLS Median Regression
Intensity Often S/R Intensity
Pooled
NHC 2.69 (0.91) 9.85 (3.16) 2.89 (1.92) 2.65 (0.97)
HC 0.32 (0.99) 1.74 (2.87) -0.29 (1.76) 0.41 (0.67)
All 1 99 (0.75) 5.37 (2.86) 3.58 (1.75) 1.62 (0.93)
Panel
NHC 5.32 (1.94) 7.42 (3.20) 4.41 (2.19) 3.13 (0.54)
HC 2.91 (2.54) 0.87 (0.19) 0.22 (0.13) 0.170 (0.06)
All 3.47 (1.40) 0.72 (1.90) 2.43 (1.31) 0.59 (0.39)
Robust Regression
Often S/R Intensity
Pooled
NHC 11.15 (3.33) 3.05 (2.00) 3.99 (0.91)
HC 1.63 (1.31) 0.26 (0.79) 0.36 (0.35)
All 6.65 (2.50) 3.66 (1.53) 2.11 (0.69)
Panel
NHC 8.64 (4.30) 7.06 (2.96) 3.45 (1.33)
HC 2.03 (1.88) -0.18 (1.30) 0.59 (0.55)
All -0.91 (2.12) 3.60 (1.43) 0.42 (0.63)
Tobit Estimation
Often S/R Intensity
Pooled
NHC 12.95 (3.40) 1.90 (2.02) 2.97 (0.92)
HC 10.54 (5.37) -2.55 (3.15) 1.06 (1.45)
All 9.13 (2.80) 1.44 (1.70) 2.18 (0.77)
Panel
NHC
HC
All
Notes: Each entry is the coefficient on seminars for that
specification of the model. The S/R indicates, "sometimes or
rarely seminar variable." Standard errors are given in
parentheses.
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in
the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.
TABLE 8
Robustness of Contribution Results
OLS
Intensity
Pooled
NHC 0.211 (0.080)
HC 0.115 (0.119)
All 0.198 (0.066)
Panel
NHC 0.407 (0.153)
HC 0.219 (0.242)
All 0.194 (0.104)
Median Regression
Often S/R Intensity
Pooled
NHC 0.475 (0.363) 0.186 (0.219) 0.155 (0.084)
HC 0.119 (0.405) 0.118 (0.247) 0.068 (0.075)
All 0.484 (0.319) 0.249 (0.192) 0.124 (0.063)
Panel
NHC 0.929 (0.506) 0.206 (0.338) 0.201 (0.084)
HC -0.837 (0.490) 0.011 (0.338) -0.084 (0.110)
All 0.248 (0.268) 0.038 (1.81) 0.105 (0.105)
Robust Regression
Often S/R Intensity
Pooled
NHC 0.690 (0.254) 0.192 (0.153) 0.169 (0.070)
HC 0.316 (0.389) 0.225 (0.231) 0.121 (0.106)
All 0.487 (0.224) 0.261 (0.135) 0.163 (0.061)
Panel
NHC 0.824 (0.426) 0.242 (0.285) 0.263 (0.123)
HC -0.518 (0.684) 0.663 (0.478) -0.090 (0.202)
All 0.265 (0.303) 0.113 (0.204) 0.113 (0.091)
Notes: Each entry is the coefficient on seminars for that
specification of the model. The S/R indicates "sometimes or
rarely seminar variable." Standard errors are given in
parentheses.
Source: Derived from KPMG Peat Marwick's Retirement Benefits in
the 1990s: 1993 and 1994 survey data.