Is the fed facilitating an unpleasant fiscal arithmetic?
Gokhale, Jagadeesh
Is the United States headed for an unprecedented economic disaster?
The fact that prominent economists are posing that question says
something about what they may be expecting. For example, in the St.
Louis Fed's Review, Kotlikoff (2006) argues that the United States
is headed for bankruptcy. Federal expenditure commitments on account of
massive government entitlement programs are growing larger and becoming
less reversible. The traditional perspective on how significant
inconsistencies between outstanding government liabilities and the
government's future expected budget balances are resolved suggests
that higher inflation could be the mechanism by which those two items
are realigned with each other.
There is ongoing debate about whether faster inflation would occur
because the Federal Reserve would eventually be forced to support the
government's future debt-financed expenditures through monetary
accommodation or whether a sudden realignment of prices could occur even
without an independent or fiscally induced monetary expansion--following
the predictions of the so-called fiscal theory of the price level
(FTPL).
This article first outlines the scope of the prospective U.S.
federal budget crunch by reporting the federal "fiscal
imbalance" and its components. The fiscal imbalance measure
compares, in present value terms, outstanding debt plus the
government's aggregate non-interest spending commitments with its
future revenues under current policies. Latest available calculations
suggest that the federal fiscal imbalance equals $63.7 trillion. The
Social Security program contributes $7.7 trillion to that amount.
Assuming that annual general revenue transfers to Medicare are not
dedicated to it, Medicare contributes $65.2 trillion, and the rest of
the federal government, which includes Medicaid, contributes $89.2
trillion. (1)
An overall fiscal imbalance of $63.7 trillion suggests that
expected future primary budget surpluses--government receipts minus
non-interest expenditures--may (or should) be considerably out of line
with the real value of outstanding government debt. Although the FTPL
would predict an immediate price level adjustment, such an adjustment
has not yet been observed. (2) And, although economists have attempted
to garner evidence in support of the FTPL by analyzing evidence from
other countries (most notably Loyo 1999), there is as yet a lack of
broad consensus about the empirical validity of the FTPL. Because the
FTPL essentially bypasses all concerns about the conduct of monetary
policy, this article says little about the FTPL beyond noting it as a
theoretically valid possibility. It devotes more attention to the
traditional monetary-policy-supported inflationary mechanism as analyzed
by Sargent and Wallace (1981).
Sargent and Wallace's "unpleasant monetarist arithmetic" provides the theoretical framework for analyzing how
U.S. fiscal and monetary policymakers could be interacting. Although
their framework is based on special assumptions about how fiscal and
monetary policies are made, it reveals the tradeoffs involved depending
on which of those two policymaking authorities acts as the
"leader" and which acts as the "follower." Most
common is to assume that the fiscal authority leads. But when it sets a
permanent path for taxes and spending involving excessive debt creation,
the monetary authority must coordinate its policies to accommodate that
path by monetizing government debt.
On the basis of more realistic assumptions about fiscal and
monetary authorities' policymaking horizons, however, this article
suggests that current world market forces and the actions of both a
"not-so-independent" Federal Reserve and shortsighted fiscal
policymakers are worsening an already severe federal budget crunch by
maintaining a severely out-of-balance fiscal policy. Continuing such a
fiscal stance over many years implies redistributing resources from
younger and future generations toward older ones. (3) That means future
generations must pay by accepting either steep benefit cuts or
permanently higher taxes, the latter possibly involving more rapid
inflation.
Plumbing the Depths of the U.S. Fiscal Hole
The seeds of the looming economic difficulties were sown many
decades ago by a combination of social insurance policies and a
protracted boom-bust sequence in fertility rates that was completed by
the mid-1960s. The consequence of that temporary fertility surge--a
76-million-strong baby-boom generation--is now approaching retirement
with expectations of substantial Social Security, Medicare, and other
entitlement transfers--roughly consistent with current benefit rules.
(4) Fulfilling those expectations for a cohort equaling one-quarter of
the total U.S. population would require steep increases in future
taxes--not least because U.S. labor force and federal revenue growth are
projected to slow just as the boomers begin retiring en masse toward the
end of the current decade. One way of raising those larger revenues may
be via faster inflation.
Table 1 shows an estimate of the U.S. fiscal imbalance with budget
projections extended without a time limit. It shows that the United
States faces a federal budget shortfall equivalent to $63.7 trillion as
of 2006 calculated under the Office of Management and Budget's
baseline economic and demographic assumptions (Gokhale and Smetters
2007). That means continuing current policies under those assumptions
involves government debt plus the excess of projected outlays over
receipts totaling $63.7 trillion in present discounted value. (5) Social
Security contributes $7.7 trillion and the Medicare program contributes
$65.2 trillion to the total federal imbalance. The rest of the federal
government's contribution to the fiscal imbalance (which includes
Medicaid) equals -$9.2 trillion. (6)
These fiscal imbalance figures have a simple interpretation: For
example, Social Security's imbalance of $7.7 trillion shows the
amount of additional resources that the government must have on hand,
invested at interest, in order to forever avoid changing Social
Security's current payroll tax and benefit policies. The same
interpretation applies to Medicare's fiscal imbalance estimate. (7)
Because the rest of the federal government account shows a negative
fiscal imbalance, that federal sector could reduce taxes or increases
outlays by as much as $9.2 trillion in present value. Of course,
overall, the federal government is short by $63.7 trillion and must
raise those resources by enacting future policy changes--reductions in
scheduled expenditures or increases in scheduled taxes or some
combination of the two. Tax increases are unlikely to be effective
because of their likely negative economic impact. Nevertheless, if the
Congress does not explicitly adopt either one of these two fiscal
approaches in the not-too-distant future, faster inflation could emerge
as a default adjustment mechanism.
Table 1 also shows that the fiscal imbalance will grow larger over
time as long as no corrective policy adjustments are undertaken. For
example, the imbalance as of 2007 amounts to $66.1 trillion since no
policy changes were enacted in 2006 to reduce its size. The accrual of
an additional $2.4 trillion to the fiscal imbalance arises because the
dates when revenue shortfalls are projected to occur move nearer to the
present with the passage of time. An alternative way to state this
outcome is that the fiscal imbalance as of 2006 accrues interest. The
current annual cost of postponing fiscal adjustments ($2.4 trillion) is
about 10 times larger than the officially reported annual deficit for
fiscal year 2006 (U.S. Treasury 2006).
If the fiscal imbalance under current policies is resolved largely
by tax-side adjustments, how high must taxes be increased? Panel C of
Table 1 shows that taxes on total payrolls would have to be increased
immediately and permanently by 14.4 percentage points--a more than
doubling of the existing payroll tax of 15.3 percent, most of which is
levied on capped payrolls. (8)
Alternatively, if the fiscal imbalance were resolved largely
through entitlement benefit cuts, those benefits (Social Security plus
Medicare) would have to be reduced by 47.4 percent immediately and
permanently. Yet another alternative would be to permanently cut all
outlays except those on Social Security and Medicare by 65.5 percent.
Table 2 shows Social Security's fiscal imbalance and its
components: Past and living generations account for more than 100
percent of the program's total fiscal imbalance ($11.0 trillion of
$7.7 trillion). That means that past and current generations stand to
reap an additional 11.0 trillion in Social Security benefits over and
above their payroll tax payments into the system (the sum of their
accumulated past benefits net of past tax payments plus their discounted
future benefits and minus their discounted future taxes). Future
generations, on the other hand, would pay $3.3 trillion in net taxes
into the system under current Social Security tax and benefit policies,
including future changes to those policies that are already scheduled.
Table 2 shows that the ratio of Social Security's fiscal
imbalance to the present value of GDP is 0.79 percent as of 2006. In
2007, that ratio will be slightly higher since no policy adjustments
were made during 2006. Table 3 shows similar information for the
Medicare program, indicating that its fiscal imbalance is about six
times larger than Social Security's fiscal imbalance. Past and
living generations are projected to receive Medicare benefits in excess
of their payroll taxes to the tune of $26.5 trillion. Thus, for Social
Security and Medicare combined, current and past generations are being
awarded about $37.5 trillion in excess benefits as a result of those
programs' policies to date.
So far, the two major political parties appear to be stuck in a
logjam, refusing to compromise on their preferred approaches to
resolving future budget shortfalls. I discuss the forces sustaining the
current budget policy logjam and why a resolution-forcing mechanism may
involve faster inflation in the following section. I also suggest that
the Federal Reserve's current commitment to price stability may
also be helping to postpone a resolution, thereby worsening the looming
federal budget crunch.
What Sustains the Current Budget Policy Logjam?
The current economic environment clearly provides no absolute
imperative for policymakers to adopt corrective fiscal adjustments
immediately. Indeed, lawmakers recently worsened the federal budget
outlook by enacting the Medicare Prescription Drug program (Medicare
Part D) in 2003 when the fiscal imbalance was already quite large and
positive, (9) and Congress may decide to enact yet more programs or
expand existing ones during the next few years to increase rather than
reduce the overall federal fiscal imbalance.
Today's budget policy logjam appears to be the result of two
interacting forces, and the lack of pressure to compromise is supported
by three features of the current economic environment. The first factor
producing the logjam is electoral pressure for politicians to deliver
ever-larger "benefits" to voter blocs while distributing the
costs as broadly as possible, which includes passing them forward to
future generations.
The second factor is conflict among current voters about
intragenerational redistribution--essentially about how entitlement and
other benefits should be financed at the margin--via tax increases or
expenditure cuts. Within a political system dominated by two major
political parties, voters' support for reducing the logjam depends
on whether their current net gains are larger on the spending or the tax
side of the budget ledger. Larger government spending implies higher
taxes, but the two need not be perfectly aligned in time. Those who are
helped more by government expenditures and hurt less by tax
increases--call them Group A--prefer expansions in the government's
role in allocating resources. Those who benefit little from government
spending but could lose significantly from tax increases--Group B--favor
a smaller role for government in allocating resources. Group B prefers
tax cuts in the hope of (eventually) reducing government-controlled
resource allocations. This is the well-known "starve the
beast" hypothesis.
One could contemplate reducing the outstanding federal fiscal
imbalance by associating each generation's current payroll taxes
with its future entitlement benefits. Cuts in the latter would then
justify cuts in the former. And if cuts in current taxes were smaller
compared to cuts in future benefits on a present value basis, the
government's financial position would improve. However, this policy
is problematic for Group A members, who fear that a program of cutting
future benefits would be expanded into cutting current ones as well
because lower current revenues would increase current federal deficits.
And they fear that cuts in current benefits would trigger additional tax
cuts and weaken a policy that they favor--government-directed resource
allocation. A resolution of the fiscal imbalance through higher current
taxes, however, is opposed by Group B members, who fear an expansion of
current intragenerational redistribution under the guise of saving the
tax increase for meeting unfunded future benefit commitments. Both sides
believe that to compromise is to surrender and fear the electoral losses
that could follow. (10)
The longer the fiscal imbalance remains unresolved, however, the
larger the cost of resolving it whether through direct fiscal policy
changes or via faster Fed-induced inflation in response to worsening
economic conditions. The political logjam between the two groups could
be described as the outcome of a "prisoners' dilemma"
game (Gokhale 2006).
Three elements of the current economic environment appear to
support postponing policy adjustments to resolve the outstanding fiscal
imbalance. First, as experience from the 1980s and 1990s suggests, the
"prisoners' dilemma" game between the two political
opponents can continue as long as the deficit outlook can be made to
appear benign or favorable. (11) Current "baseline" budget
projections by the Congressional Budget Office, which suggest very low
debt accumulations through the next decade, achieve just that. Second,
experience from the 1970s suggests that stable prices are an important
element for ensuring a benign economic outlook. The Federal
Reserve's strong commitment to and high credibility among fiscal
policymakers for delivering current price stability are an important
element for establishing a benign economic outlook. Finally, high saving
in foreign saving and their preference for "investing" in the
United States reduces world interest rates and keeps the dollar
overvalued on currency markets despite massive U.S. trade deficits,
again allowing postponement of fiscal adjustments. The following
subsections examine the dimensions of each of those factors in greater
detail.
The Budget Outlook: Baseline versus Alternative
Partly as a result of recent higher-than-average economic growth,
federal revenues have grown robustly and have reduced deficit
projections over the next few years. According to the Congressional
Budget Office's 2006 projections, the federal budget deficit is
expected to shrink from 1.9 percent of GDP ($248 billion/$13,308
billion) to just 0.4 percent of GDP ($93 billion /$21,052 billion) by
2016 (CBO 2006). (12)
However, the "current law" baseline on which those
projections are based includes several elements that may not be
realized. It assumes that war outlays will remain fixed in dollar terms
rather than grow over time; that the AMT will remain unreformed; and
that recent tax cuts won't be extended beyond their
"sunset" dates. Although the Congressional Budget Office is
constrained to adopt a strict "current law" basis when making
baseline budget projections, other CBO reports show the implications of
alternative assumptions.
For example, CBO's Budget Outlook from August 2006 shows that
if all of the revenue side-alternatives--extending recent tax cuts and
reforming the Alternative Minimum Tax--are included, and if Iraq and
Afghanistan war outlays are assumed to grow with nominal GDP, projected
deficits during the next 10 years would be much larger: the 2016 deficit
would equal 4.6 percent of GDP ($962 billion/$21,052 billion) instead of
just 0.4 percent of GDP under the baseline. Nevertheless, policymakers
generally focus on CBO's benign "baseline" projections
that stymie pressures for early action on deeper budget reforms.
The CBO's long-range projections also exhibit widely different
outcomes. Assuming intermediate federal spending levels and higher
revenues (from continuation of current AMT law and bracket creep),
federal spending is estimated to increase to 38 percent of GDP by 2050,
but federal debt held by the public would increase to just 100 percent
of GDP by that year. Under lower assumed revenues (laws are periodically
amended to hold revenues at their historical average of 18.3 percent of
GDP), the ratio of debt held by the public to GDP explodes to more than
300 percent of GDP by 2050. Such wide variation in possible budget
outcomes implies that capital market participants should incorporate
high risk or inflation premiums in the interest rates they demand on
government debt. However, persistence of low long-term interest rates
suggests that capital markets may be weighting downside budget risks
insufficiently.
The Federal Reserve's Emphasis on Price Stability
The Federal Reserve's strong emphasis on maintaining price
stability is grounded in the belief--supported by historical
experience--that there is no stable and exploitable tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment. That perspective holds that price stability
itself delivers maximum sustainable economic growth by helping
individuals and firms to clearly perceive the true tradeoffs involved in
different uses of their resources.
However, is the Federal Reserve committed to delivering price
stability permanently or just "current" price stability?
According to Sargent and Wallace (1981), the extent of the Fed's
commitment is important in determining the course of fiscal policy
adopted by the Fed's principal--Congress. By most accounts, that
study is said to reveal the dire implications of lax fiscal discipline
for future inflation. In the short term, the Fed's effective
commitment to maintaining price stability clearly contributes toward
maintaining a benign or favorable economic outlook. As such, it may be
helping to prolong the fiscal policy logjam--thereby worsening the
long-term fiscal outlook. Fiscal policymakers may (erroneously) believe
that delays in adopting fiscal reforms will not prove costly because the
Fed's actions would ensure a robust economy. Furthermore, although
fiscal policymakers may believe that the Fed would remain steadfast in
delivering price stability, their failure to undertake pro-active
policies to resolve fiscal imbalances and, indeed, continued enactment
of policies that worsen them, could unhinge the Fed's ability to
maintain price stability. The next section explores this line of
reasoning in greater detail with reference to Sargent and Wallace's
(1981) "unpleasant monetarist arithmetic."
Growing Foreign Ownership of U.S. Government Debt
The government's current policies--generous entitlement
benefits, high (war-related) discretionary spending growth, and low
taxes--may be maintained for a few more years--but only as long as
foreign savers continue to lend resources to the United States at low
interest rates. Such "pro-consumption" policies have caused
rapid growth in U.S. goods and service imports, increased the trade
deficit, and made the U.S. net investment position vis-a-vis the rest of
the world more negative. According to the U.S. Bureau of Economic
Analysis, the U.S. net asset position--U.S.-owned assets abroad minus
foreign-owned assets in the United States--is at an all-time low of
-$2.6 trillion, and the U.S. current account balance reached -$791
billion during 2005. (13)
Foreign borrowing capacity is an important component of the
"debt constraint" that the federal government may confront as
population-aging-related budget deficits begin to accrue. The recent
trend of foreign capital inflows in the United States indicates that the
share of U.S. government debt held by foreign residents and institutions
increased especially rapidly during the 1990s--from 21 percent in 1994
to 53 percent in 2004 (Figure 1). A similar trend--of increasing
nonresident-held government debt share--is evident in European countries
(Figure 2).
[FIGURES 1-2 OMITTED]
When today's consumption-oriented fiscal policies encounter a
binding debt constraint will depend on how much longer that trend
continues via foreigners' desire for high saving and for parking
those funds in U.S. Treasury securities. If and when the constraint
becomes effective, the federal government will be forced to increase
taxes and cut benefits to avoid sharp increases in interest rates from
growing federal deficits. However, the longer that the current political
logjam prevents an earlier adoption of such fiscal adjustment, the more
the pressure on the Federal Reserve to shift priorities--away from
maintaining current price stability and toward accommodating growing
federal debt to prevent high interest rates from immediately reducing
economic growth and employment. (14) Thus, the current political logjam
over fiscal reforms increases the chance of market-precipitated economic
and policy adjustments, which would likely cause considerably more
damage and impose larger costs on those least able to bear them. (15)
The Monetary-Fiscal Connection
As mentioned in the earlier section, the longer the
"prisoners' dilemma" game between the two political
parties continues, the more "locked in" future entitlement
outlays become. However, the firmer the fiscal authority's
commitment to an unsustainable policy (or, in this case, the weaker its
commitment to adjust policies), the worse the tradeoff faced by the
monetary authority. To explore the link between fiscal commitments and
the monetary authority's options, this section provides a brief
sketch of the "unpleasant monetarist arithmetic" proposed by
Sargent and Wallace (1981). It also briefly describes the rationale
underlying the "Fiscal Theory of the Price Level," which
confers primacy on fiscal policy in directly determining the price
level--without any concomitant monetary expansion. That is followed by a
discussion of the implications of the current fiscal stance for monetary
policy and vice versa.
The Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic
One component of the connection between monetary and fiscal
policies is the public's demand for a "monetary"
asset--for use, primarily, as an exchange medium. Today's monetary
systems depend on "flat" money issued by the government, which
serves as the basic monetary asset--also called "base" or
"reserve" money. (16) Total money creation by the banking
system is limited by the amount of base money in circulation and by
"reserve requirements" and other regulations that bank
deposits are subjected to by the Federal Reserve System.
Two features of the government's supply of base money are
important: First, although base money constitutes its liability, the
government pays zero nominal interest to its holders. Therefore, private
agents' demand for real money balances is inversely related to
prevailing market (nominal) interest rates. The Sargent and Wallace
study assumes that real market interest rates (and all real variables
such as income and consumption) are fixed. That is, the economy remains
in a "real steady state." In turn, that means the private
sector's demand for money balances would be inversely related to
the prevailing inflation rate. The second component is the Federal
Reserve's monopoly over the supply of base money, which enables it
to be used as a fiscal instrument to generate seinorage revenues.
The Fed determines how much of the government's outstanding
public debt it should purchase in exchange for base money (through
"open-market operations") to achieve its current price level
(or inflation) objective. A larger fraction of existing government debt
held by the central bank (instead of by the public at large) produces
larger seinorage revenues. (17) However, it also implies a larger stock
of base money circulating with commercial and other banks, and a
correspondingly larger potential for increasing the amount of liquid
("monetary") assets in the economy. All other things being
equal, a larger supply of liquidity induces proportionally greater
inflationary pressure. Given that all real variables are fixed in the
"'real steady state'" economy, an increase in liquid
assets by x percent would increase the price level--also by x percent.
Now consider the choices of the fiscal authority that must finance
a series of expenditures from its tax receipts through time. Because,
like all private citizens, it cannot spend each dollar of revenues
(taxes plus seinorage) more than once, any debt incurred to cover past
revenue shortfalls must be repaid (or serviced) out of future primary
budget surpluses. In addition, the government faces a "debt
constraint" defined by the public's unwillingness to hold more
than a given amount of real government debt per unit of real income.
(18)
Within this framework, monetary policymakers face an intertemporal
choice if fiscal policy is pre-committed--that is, if the series of
future government nominal revenues, expenditures, and associated
deficits are fixed--and the implied future nominal debt levels would
breach the private-sector's debt-holding limit. That choice is
between achieving lower inflation today versus in the future. Why?
Because the Fed would have to generate adequate seinorage to ensure that
the public's debt limit is not breached. Then, if the Fed
maintained low inflation today by selling government securities and
reducing the ratio of liquid to other assets in private agents'
portfolios, it would also reduce current seinorage and hasten the day
when the private-sector's debt limit becomes binding. That directly
implies the need for a compensating increase in seinorage and inflation
tomorrow by purchasing government bonds and allowing larger money
creation. (19)
The usual interpretation of such "unpleasant monetarist
arithmetic" is that a fiscal authority that is committed to a
specific policy course can force the Federal Reserve into a dilemma--of
choosing lower current inflation at the expense of higher future
inflation. But an alternative possibility is that the monetary authority
may be able to discipline the fiscal authority by holding steadfast to
its price-stability objective through time. In that case, the fiscal
authority must retreat from a profligate fiscal policy when its
expenditure commitments cannot be financed via additional debt creation.
The key lesson, however, is that both the Federal Reserve and
Congress cannot commit to independent and inconsistent monetary and
fiscal policies, respectively. A locked-in and irreversible fiscal
policy means that the Federal Reserve must eventually coordinate its
policy to generate adequate seinorage revenues. As noted earlier,
waiting longer to resolve existing fiscal imbalances directly locks in
federal expenditure commitments and, if taxes cannot be increased, locks
in debt creation. Then the Fed's commitment to maintaining low
inflation today directly implies higher inflation tomorrow.
The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level
Sargent and Wallace note that the "unpleasant monetarist
arithmetic" is consistent with reversing the role of
"leader" and "follower." A sufficiently strong
commitment by the monetary authority to price stability could be
successful if it forces the fiscal authority to revert to fiscal
prudence. Thus, a strong commitment to price stability by the monetary
authority is by itself sufficient to guarantee price stability. The
fiscal theory of the price level challenges this notion of sufficiency
and suggests that without an appropriate fiscal policy, the monetary
authority's commitment to price stability by itself won't work
no matter how strong it is. Thus a central bank should not only be
sufficiently independent to set the correct monetary policy; it must
also be able to cajole its principal into following a fiscal policy
consistent with achieving stable prices. (20)
In simple terms, fiscal policy is consistent with price stability
if the present value of expected future primary budget surpluses equals
the real value of outstanding government debt (nominal debt divided by
the price index). That is, if
(1) [D.sub.t]/[P.sub.t] = $5 trillion/1 = Expected present value of
future primary budget surpluses.
Here, [D.sub.t] represents outstanding government debt and
[P.sub.t] represents the price level in the current period t. [P.sub.t]
is set to unity for simplicity. Equation (1) says that the public's
willingness to hold government debt worth $5 trillion in today's
dollars must be supported by an expectation that it will be repaid--that
is, future primary surpluses will be sufficiently large to accommodate
interest costs of the existing debt of $5 trillion. Validating that
expectation would require the government to generate $5 trillion in
future budget surpluses.
According to the FTPL, equation (1) should be viewed not as a
constraint on government's intertemporal budget choices, but as an
equilibrium condition. Given the monetary authority's commitment to
price stability, if the fiscal authority undertakes no adjustments to
spending or taxes despite explosive growth in the real value of debt
([D.sub.t]/[P.sub.t]), then the FTPL predicts an immediate price level
adjustment in order to restore balance between the real value of debt
and public expectations about future budget surpluses. (21) Thus,
operating a fiscal policy that is considerably out of sync with the
requirements of price stability would trigger an inflationary
adjustment--even without a fiscally induced monetary expansion.
If the right-hand side of equation (1) is replaced by "present
value of future primary surpluses under current policies," we get
-$58.7 trillion instead of $5 trillion. That is, the gap between the
current fiscal policy stance and the public's expectations about
future budget surpluses (which must equal $5 trillion because it
voluntarily holds outstanding federal debt) is a massive $63.7 trillion.
The FTPL predicts that a sufficiently large gap between the future
implications of current policies and the public's expectations
would trigger a sudden inflationary surge that equilibrates the two.
Adjustment Alternatives
Since no equilibrating price level adjustments have occurred so
far, either the deviation of prospective budget surpluses under
"current policy" from those "expected" by the public
is not large, or the public expects fiscal policy adjustments to occur
sufficiently early to warrant a continuation of the apparent disconnect between the two. However, the difference between the two appears to be
quite large, and there appears to be little prospect that the budget
policy logjam will be resolved soon.
Note that high deficits and debt accumulation during the 1980s and
early 1990s were brought under control by budget constraints adopted
between 1990 and 2002. (22) That experience could be driving current
public expectations that fiscal policymakers will respond similarly to
future increases in debt levels. However, the cause of high deficits
during those earlier decades was spiraling discretionary
appropriations--especially the defense build-up of the 1980s. Future
increases in deficit and debt levels will be driven by entitlement
programs, public support for which is considerably stronger. Hence,
future deficits are likely to become more difficult to pare back through
spending cuts the longer the fiscal policy logjam continues. A third
possibility, however, is that we will witness either a Fed-accommodated
increase in inflation or a FTPL-driven price level adjustment in the
future as federal spending commitments become firmer, fiscal authorities
cannot implement tax hikes for fear of weakening the economy, and
investors and the public begin anticipating higher capital and borrowing
costs as federal debt grows more explosive than current baseline
projections suggest and absorbs investible resources.
Is Federal Reserve Policy Aiding an Unpleasant Fiscal Arithmetic?
As noted earlier, the Sargent and Wallace unpleasant monetarist
arithmetic is anchored on a monetarist model wherein real
variables--output, employment, consumption, and interest rates--remain
Fixed irrespective of inflation or government taxes and spending.
That's clearly not a good approximation in the short term, and
it's also not likely to be true in the long term. Indeed, there is
little point in discussing the monetary-fiscal policy tradeoff if
profligate fiscal policy affects only inflation and nominal aggregates
and has no impact on real economic magnitudes in the long term. The
monetarist model is therefore useful only for clarifying the underlying
pressures that could force the Fed to monetize a larger share of
government debt and trigger permanently faster inflation. Subsequently,
this may generate slower productivity growth and permanently reduced
employment, output, and consumption. (23)
Note also that the analysis does not pin down which of the two
policy authorities (fiscal or monetary) makes a firmer commitment to a
prespecified policy rule. As mentioned earlier, most discussions suggest
that if the monetary authority sticks to its price stability commitment
(say, by announcing a fixed money growth rate rule), the fiscal
authority must back down and alter the path of future deficits. But
that, again, means higher job-destroying taxes or cuts in benefits and
reduced aggregate expenditures.
This "game of chicken" between monetary and fiscal
authorities requires one of them to move first and fix a sequence of
policy actions throughout the future. The other authority must then
coordinate its actions to the fixed policy of the first authority, given
the budget constraint it faces. In reality, however, announcing and
adhering to a policy rule in perpetuity are obviously not how policies
are made. Under existing political and economic institutions, fiscal and
monetary policymakers may have different operational time horizons. It
seems reasonable to assume that fiscal policymakers have shorter time
horizons over which to achieve their personal or political goals--as
dictated by relatively short electoral cycles and the uncertainty of
electoral outcomes. The Federal Reserve, however, has an extended
"institutional" memory because of its long-serving personnel
and operational traditions. In addition, the Federal Reserve makes
effective policy adjustments throughout the year whose sizes can be
calibrated to emerging economic information, whereas tax policies take
time to enact and are subject to lobbying and manipulation by particular
interest groups.
In such an institutional environment, the Federal Reserve's
current and apparently firm commitment to maintaining price stability
could be generating an "unpleasant fiscal arithmetic." Each
generation of relatively shortsighted fiscal policymakers may have the
incentive to postpone implementing unpopular policies and "pass the
buck" to the next generation of fiscal policymakers. And such
postponement becomes more feasible if policymakers and the public are
convinced of a continued benign or favorable economic outlook. One
element aiding such an outlook is the Fed's effective commitment to
low inflation and inflation expectations. In the meanwhile, however, the
large fiscal imbalance accrues interest and grows larger. Indeed, a
Fed-supported benign economic outlook may encourage fiscal policymakers
to undertake additional unfunded spending commitments without much risk
of immediate adverse economic effects. (24)
According to this reasoning, the Fed's high credibility in
delivering current price stability may eventually worsen the tradeoffs
that future fiscal policymakers (and, as conjectured by Sargent and
Wallace, future monetary policymakers) will face. Indeed, with
relatively shortsighted fiscal policymakers, such a worsening may emerge
from cumulatively profligate policies adopted by successive groups of
fiscal policymakers when no such (binding) tradeoff existed to begin
with. As mentioned earlier, recent policy decisions to increase the size
of the U.S. fiscal imbalances appear consistent with such reasoning.
Does it follow, then, that the monetary authorities should not
pursue price stability as steadfastly? Not necessarily. That's
because although recent emphasis on price stability appears not to have
improved fiscal discipline--and, perhaps, may have contributed to lax
fiscal policies--it does not imply that the alternative of allowing
faster inflation would induce better behavior among fiscal policymakers.
The bottom line is simply that the Fed's current commitment to
price stability may be temporarily helping to prolong rather than
resolve the political logjam and the federal fiscal imbalance is growing
larger as time passes. The Fed's future commitment to price
stability would have to be extremely rigid and unyielding if faster
inflation is to be avoided as a means of resolving that imbalance--and
it would work only if the FTPL's potential impact remains dormant.
Conclusion
The game between monetary and fiscal policymakers is usually
analyzed with reference to the unpleasant monetarist arithmetic. That
analysis suggests that if one of those policymakers leads by setting an
immutable policy rule, the other must follow and coordinate its policy
with the leader in order to satisfy the government's intertemporal
budget constraint. When the monetary authority is the follower and the
federal government's predetermined fiscal policy breaches the
public's debt-holding limit, the Fed's policy tradeoff
consists of achieving low inflation today or low inflation tomorrow, but
not both. Despite its commitment to maintaining price stability, it must
eventually monetize a larger share of government debt and help finance
the government's precommitted outlays. Alternatively under the
fiscal theory of the price level, budget policies that are inconsistent
with the real value of outstanding government debt would trigger an
inflationary realignment of prices independent of any monetary
accommodation of government debt. The FTPL, however, lacks adequate
empirical validation as yet.
This article describes the economic forces sustaining the current
stalemate on reforms to resolve large existing fiscal imbalances under
current policies. The budget reform logjam--a conflict between
preferences over inter- and intra-generational redistribution--appears
to be sustained by three elements: current budget reporting that helps
policymakers to highlight a benign budget outlook, a surge in global
saving allowing continuation of pro-consumption fiscal policies, and the
Federal Reserve's current commitment to maintaining price stability
that helps to coordinate the public's and policymakers'
expectations about a benign or favorable economic outlook.
Unfortunately, under alternative and perhaps more realistic
assumptions, the fiscal outlook is far from benign. Calculations based
on extended official budget data suggest that current policies imply a
fiscal imbalance (in perpetuity) of $67.2 trillion that must be paid out
of future revenues or reduced via government expenditure cuts. Social
Security and Medicare appear to be the chief sources of the large fiscal
imbalance.
Finally, the article suggests the possibility that the Fed's
commitment to price stability may be assisting an unpleasant fiscal
arithmetic by relatively shortsighted fiscal policymakers. Under
expectations of a stable or favorable economic outlook over the short
term and of a Fed steadfastly delivering price stability, fiscal
policymakers have recently enacted massive increases in government
expenditure commitments. If the political logjam remains unresolved,
outstanding fiscal imbalances will grow larger over time, forcing larger
future debt creation that may push the Federal Reserve off its emphasis
on price stability. In that case, current projections of a benign
economic outlook won't be validated. Whether the much-lauded
independence of the Federal Reserve is ensuring sustainable economic
growth without inflation or contributing to the eventual weakening of
the economy and faster future inflation is still an open question.
References
Auerbach, A. J.; Gokhale, J.; and Kotlikoff, L. J. (1991)
"Generational Accounts: A Meaningful Alternative to Deficit
Accounting." In D. Bradford (ed.) Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol.
5, 55-110. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press for the National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Bernanke, B. S. (2006) "The Coming Demographic Transition:
Will We Treat Future Generations Fairly?" Speech delivered to the
Washington Economic Club (October 4). Available at
www.federalreserve.gov/ boarddocs/speeches/2006/20061004/default.htm.
Congressional Budget Office (2005) "The Long-Term Budget
Outlook," A CBO Study (December).
--(2006) "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update"
(August 17).
Dominitz, J.; Manski, C. F.; and Heinz, J. (2001) "Social
Security Expectations and Retirement Saving Decisions." Mimeo,
Northwestern University.
Gokhale, J. (2006) "Congressional Prisoners"
Dilemma." Tech Central Station Daily (May 24). Available at
www.cato.org/pub_display.php? pub_id=6405.
Gokhale, J., and Smetters, K. (2006) "Fiscal and Generational
Imbalances: An Update." Tax Policy and the Economy 20: 194-223.
--(2007) "'Do the Markets Care about the $2.4 Trillion
U.S. Deficit?" Financial Analysts' Journal 63 (2): 37-47.
Kotlikoff, L. J. (2006) "Is the United States Bankrupt?"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 88: 235-50.
Loyo, E. (1999) "Tight Money Paradox on the Loose: A Fiscalist
Hyperinflation." Unpublished manuscript, Kennedy School of
Government, Harvard University.
Sargent, T. J., and Wallace, N. (1981) "Some Unpleasant
Monetarist Arithmetic." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapllis
Quarterly Review 5: 1-17.
U. S. Treasury (2006) Announcement on the Budget Deficit for Fiscal
Year 2006. Available at www.treas.gov/press/releases/hp135.htm.
(1) If general revenue transfers were considered to be dedicated to
Medicare, that program's fiscal imbalance would be reduced, but
that of the rest of the government would be increased by an identical
amount, leaving the total fiscal imbalance estimate unchanged.
(2) The FTPL would also predict a similar price level adjustment
whenever changes to fiscal policies widen the gap between real debt
outstanding and expected future primary surpluses. Major legislation
such as the Medicare prescription drag law enacted in "2003 is an
obvious candidate for consideration in this context. However, no
significant price level realignment attributable to the passage of the
prescription drag law was observed around that time.
(3) The first major treatise on the measurement of U.S.
intergenerational redistribution through fiscal policies was completed
more than 15 years ago. See Auerbach, Gokhale, and Kotlikoff (1991).
(4) Most studies on individual expectations of future Social
Security benefits suggest that younger people are more skeptical than
older ones of receiving benefits. However, conditioned on the continued
existence of the Social Security system, most people expect to receive
benefits consistent with current levels. See Dominitz, Manski, and Heinz
(2001).
(5) Debt worth $63.7 trillion would not actually accumulate because
the government would be forced to change fiscal and monetary policies at
some point in the future in order to pay off accumulating debt.
Fiscal-imbalance-type measures are useful, however, to show the
magnitude of the mismatch between outstanding debt and future budget
balances under current policies.
(6) This assumes that general revenues used to finance a part of
the Supplementary Medical Insurance program and the entire Medicare Part
D (prescription drag) program represent resources that are
"appropriated" rather than "dedicated" to those
programs. Under the latter assumption, Medicare's fiscal imbalance
would equal $24 trillion rather than $65 trillion. However, under that
assumption, the imbalance on account of the rest of the federal
government would be $3"2 trillion rather than -$9 trillion.
(7) This assumes that the general revenue transfers to Medicare are
"appropriated" for that program rather than
"dedicated" to it. See Gokhale and Smetters (2006) for a
fuller discussion of this issue.
(8) The Social Security employer plus employee payroll tax of 12.4
percent is levied on capped payrolls. The 2.9 percent employer plus
employee Medicare payroll tax is not subject to a similar ceiling on
taxable employee compensation.
(9) Estimates from 2003 excluding the Bush administration's
proposed Medicare Part D outlays would have shown a U.S, fiscal
imbalance of $38.1 trillion,
(10) Demand-side economic management and stabilization through
fiscal policy generally require more information generation and
processing than is feasible for timely policy implementation by Congress
and the administration. Adherents to establishing a stable and credible
low-tax environment and allowing private entrepreneurship, innovation,
and free trade to direct economic resources to their best uses following
market-generated price signals seem to have grown in number in recent
years--especially after Reagan-era tax cuts ushered in two-plus decades
of robust economic growth, interrupted only by two mild economic
recessions.
(11) Recall experience from the early and mid 1990s, when an
outside presidential candidate (Ross Perot) successfully played on the
dangers of higher projected deficits to get many voters to defect from
the two major parties.
(12) The CBO's long-range projections (CBO 2005), however,
assuming intermediate spending levels and higher revenues (from
continuation of current AMT law and bracket creep) show federal spending
rising to 38 percent of GDP and federal debt held by the public
increasing to 100 percent of GDP by 2050. Under lower assumed revenues
(where laws are periodically changed to hold revenues at their
historical average of 18.3 percent of GDP), the ratio of debt held by
the public to GDP explodes to more than 300 percent of GDP by 2050.
(13) Measured at current cost. See the comparison between U.S. net
investment positions for 2004 and 2005 in the latest BEA bulletins
available at www.bea.gov/bea/di/intinv05_tl.xls and
www.bea.gov/bea/newsrelarchive/2006/trans206.xls.
(14) It is instructive to note that total EU countries'
general government debt amounted to 4.7 trillion [euro] by July 2006.
This debt level (and the foreign-held component) can only be expected to
increase as European population-aging-related budget deficits increase
during coming years.
(15) External or total debt constraints are unlikely to be of a
fixed magnitude--even as ratios to an income measure such as GDP. New
information about productivity, labor market regulations, the prospect
of new debt issues, and the likelihood of default mean that the
government's ability to borrow for supporting current consumption
(or its sensitivity to market interest rates) could change considerably
over time.
(16) Government-issued flat money serves as the basis for the
creation of "near money" substitutes that also perform
"monetary" functions for the private sector--such as bank
checking and saving deposits, money market accounts, etc. However,
monopoly control over the supply of "base" money enables the
government (or the central bank as the government's agent) to
control the total amount of monetary assets in the economy.
(17) Each year, the Fed returns earnings on its government bonds
portfolio--net of operating costs--to the Treasury.
(18) The debt constraint does not necessarily imply a fixed
quantity of government bonds that the private sector is willing to hold.
It could reflect an increasingly interest-inelastic demand for
government bonds (or supply of loanable funds) at higher levels of total
private-sector holdings of those bonds.
(19) Under certain circumstances--especially if today's money
demand is highly sensitive to future expected inflation, a monetary
policy that promises to deliver a higher pace of future money creation
in exchange for slower current money creation may generate higher
expected inflation--which, in turn, could increase current inflation
despite low current money creation.
(20) The speech by Ben S. Bernanke, chairman of the Federal Open
Market Committee, to the Washington Economic Club may be viewed under
this perspective as an attempt to nudge fiscal policy toward greater
prudence--to safeguard the Fed's long-term credibility in
delivering low inflation. The speech is available at
www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/ speeches/2006/20061004/default.htm.
(21) Note that the government's budget constraint can assume a
price-setting role if the traditional equation of exchange approach is
inadequate to fix the price level. That is, either the money supply is
endogenous, or the current price level depends on future price
expectations--directly, or because short-term movements in output depend
on short-term price movements, etc. In such eases, multiple price level
sequences through time could be consistent with the equation of
exchange, and the government's intertemporal budget constraint
could become instrumental in determining which price level path is
realized.
(22) The Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 was extended through 2002
and imposed spending caps on discretionary expenditures and anti-deficit
increasing PAYGO restrictions on new entitlement expenditure increases.
(23) Permanently higher inflation would result from government debt
growth breaching the public's debt-holding limit. It would generate
larger inflation-tax revenues to service that debt if fiscal
policymakers refuse to increase direct taxes. Some people contend that
raising adequate revenues via seinorage would never be feasible.
However, whether additional revenue to finance irreversible benefit
commitments is eventually obtained from permanently faster inflation or
higher direct taxes is not the crucial issue. Rather, it is whether
inability or refusal to implement corrective fiscal reforms would
compromise the Fed's price stability objective. If it did, interest
rates would increase and growth in hours worked, output, and consumption
would decline in a high-inflation environment.
(24) Note that, in the monetarist model of Sargent and Wallace
(1981), there can be no adverse impact on real output, consumption, or
interest rates. To the extent those assumptions are not satisfied in the
real world, faster current inflation may have adverse effects on real
output, employment, etc. and spoil the expectations coordination
discussed in the text.
Jagadeesh Gokhale is a Senior Fellow at the Cato Institute. He
thanks Jim Dorn, Peter Van Doren, and William Niskanen for comments on
earlier drafts and Joanne Fung for research assistance.
TABLE 1
U.S. FEDERAL FISCAL IMBALANCE AND ITS COMPONENTS
Panel A. Present Values in Billions of Constant 2006 Dollars
FY2006 FY2007
Total Fiscal Imbalance--
U.S. Federal Government 63,675 66,118
Social Security 7,684 8,017
Medicare 65,181 67,578
Rest of Federal Government -9,190 -9,477
Panel B. As a Percent of the Present Value of GDP
Total Fiscal Imbalance--
U.S. Federal Government 6.6 6.6
Social Security 0.8 0.8
Medicare 6.7 6.8
Rest of Federal Government -0.9 -0.9
Panel C. As a Percent of the Present Value of (Uncapped) Payrolls
Total Fiscal Imbalance--
U.S. Federal Government 14.4 14.5
Social Security 1.7 1.8
Medicare 14.7 14.8
Rest of Federal Government -2.1 -2.1
NOTE: Discount rate = 3.65 percent, consistent with rates on 30-year
Treasuries outstanding; Terminal labor productivity growth rate = 1.8
percent, consistent with the economic assumptions of the Office of
Management and Budget under the Budget for the United States
Government, Fiscal Year 2007; AMT fix applied for the next 10 years
only. Allowance made for higher revenues from bracket creep throughout
the projections. Figures as a percent of the present value of payrolls
use the Medicare wage tax base.
SOURCE: Authors' calculations.
TABLE 2
SOCIAL SECURITY'S FISCAL AND GENERATIONAL IMBALANCES
Panel A. Present Values in Billions of Constant 2004 Dollars
FY2006 FY2007
Total Fiscal Imbalance in
Social Security 7,684 8,017
Past and Living Generations (GI) 11,019 11,405
Future Net Benefits of
Living Generations (a) 13,039 13,570
Trust Fund -2,020 -2,164
Future Generation (b) -3,335 -3,389
Panel B. As a Percent of the Present Value of GDP
Total Fiscal Imbalance in
Social Security 0.79 0.80
Past and Living Generations (GI) 1.14 1.14
Future Net Benefits of
Living Generations (a) 1.34 1.36
Trust Fund -0.21 -0.22
Future Generations (b) -0.34 -0.34
Panel C. As a Percent of the Present Value of (Uncapped) Payrolls
Total Fiscal Imbalance in
Social Security 1.73 1.76
Past and Living Generations (GI) 2.49 2.50
Future Net Benefits of
Living Generations (a) 2.94 2.98
Trust Fund -0.46 -0.47
Future Generations (b) -0.75 -0.74
(a) Those born 15 years ago and earlier. In the year 2004, for example,
this category includes people born before 1990.
(b) Those born 14 years ago and later. In the year 2004, for example,
this category includes people born during 1990 and later.
SOURCE: Authors' calculations.
TABLE 3
MEDICARE'S FISCAL AND GENERATIONAL IMBALANCES
Panel A. Present Values in Billions of Constant 2004 Dollars
FY2006 FY2007
Total Fiscal Imbalance in Medicare 65,181 67,578
Past and Living Generations (GI) 26,496 27,791
Future Net Benefits of
Living Generations (a) 26,828 28,141
Trust Fund -332 -349
Future Generation (b) 38,685 39,787
Panel B. As a Percent of the Present Value of GDP
Total Fiscal Imbalance in Medicare 6.72 6.77
Past and Living Generations (GI) 2.73 2.78
Future Net Benefits of
Living Generations (a) 2.76 2.82
Trust Fund -0.03 -0.03
Future Generations (b) 3.99 3.99
Panel C. As a Percent of the Present Value of (Uncapped) Payrolls
Total Fiscal Imbalance in Medicare 14.70 14.83
Past and Living Generations (GI) 5.98 6.10
Future Net Benefits of
Living Generations (a) 6.05 6.18
Trust Fund -0.07 -0.08
Future Generation (b) 8.73 8.73
(a) Those born 15 years ago and earlier. In the year 2004, for
example, this category includes people born before 1990.
(b) Those born 14 years ago and later. In the year 2004, for example,
this category includes people born during 1990 and later.
SOURCE: Authors' calculations.