SAVING-INVESTMENT CONNECTION: EVIDENCE FROM THE ASEAN COUNTRIES.
Anoruo, Emmanuel
Abstract
The relationship between saving and investment has been sharply
debated in the literature following the pioneering work of Feldstein and
Horioka (1980). This paper extends this debate to the ASEAN countries by
using cointegration procedure in time-series analysis. Specifically,
three analyses are conducted. First, saving and investment are tested to
determine the order of integration using both the Dickey-Fuller (DF) and
augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) approaches. Second, the long-run
equilibrium relationship between saving and investment is explored by
utilizing the cointegration tests proposed by Johansen and Juselius
(1990). Third, Granger-causality tests based on vector error-correction
models (VECM) are undertaken to ascertain the direction of causality between the two series. The results indicate that saving and investment
are integrated of order one [I(1)]. Based on the cointegration results,
saving and investment are found to share long-run equilibrium
association. The Granger-causality tests reveal tha t investment causes
saving in the cases of Indonesia and Singapore. For the Philippines,
causality runs from saving to investment. As for Malaysia and Thailand,
the results suggest bi-directional causality between saving and
investment.
1. INTRODUCTION
The theoretical finding by Feldstein and Horioka (1980) that saving
and investment are highly correlated has generated intense debate in the
economics literature. Feldstein and Horioka interpreted the high
correlation between saving and investment as evidence of imperfect capital mobility across national boundaries. This finding is
inconsistent with the conventional wisdom, which stipulates that in the
absence of financial controls, capital should flow between countries in
search of the highest rate of return. However, if capital movements were
restricted, domestic saving and investment will be highly correlated.
The existence of strong association between saving and investment has
been validated by Feldstein (1983), Summers (1988), Baxter and Crucini
(1993), Dooley, Frankel, and Mathieson (1987), Caprio and Howard (1984),
Feldstein and Bacchetta (1989), Miller (1988), and Tesar (1991). In
general, these studies contend that capital is not internationally
mobile. Under this assumption, increases in domestic saving, all things
being equal, will stimulate domestic investment since capital is not
flowing across country borders in search of the highest return.
However a number of researchers including Murphy (1984), Obstfeld
(1986), Finn (1990), Stockman and Tesar (1991), and Barkoulas,
Filizetkin, and Murphy (1996) have challenged the existence of high
correlation between saving and investment. These authors surmise that
capital is internationally mobile. Under this hypothesis, foreign
capital flows to countries with higher real interest rates. Perfect
capital mobility, has important policy implications especially for small
open economies. In the event that capital were internationally perfectly
mobile, increases in domestic saving do not necessarily translate into
higher domestic investment because foreign savings generally flow to
countries with higher real interest rates.
Although the previous studies in the literature have furnished insights with regard to the relationship between saving and investment,
the conceptual and methodological approaches utilized in these studies
present a number of concerns. First, most of the studies used single
equation ordinary least squares (OLS) regression method to examine the
relationship between saving and investment. These studies are likely to
suffer from simultaneous equation bias leading to fallacious
conclusions. Second, studies that employed OLS regression analysis did
so without first examining the time series properties (unit roots) of
saving and investment. Nelson and Plosser (1982) have shown that most
macroeconomic time series data are nonstationary in their levels but
stationary when differenced. Third, a number of studies used
cross-section data, which makes it difficult, if not impossible, to
apply their findings to any particular country. Fourth and finally, most
of the studies in the literature concentrated on the relations hip
between saving and investment in the developed countries [mainly for the
members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)] with little or no attention devoted to countries with nascent economies.
This paper attempts to overcome these weaknesses by using recent
advances in cointegration techniques and country-specific time series
data to examine the long-run equilibrium relationship between saving and
investment for the ASEAN countries specifically, Indonesia, Malaysia,
Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand. In particular, we conduct unit
root tests using both the Dickey-Fuller (DF) and augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF) to determine the order of integration, since we must only include
variables with the same order of integration in the cointegrating
equation. In addition, we undertake the cointegration tests utilizing
the maximum-likelihood procedure suggested by Johansen and Juselius
(1990) and Johansen (1991) to ascertain the long-run relationship
between saving and investment. [1] Finally, the Granger-causality tests
based on the vector error correction models (VECM) are conducted to
determine the direction of causality between saving and investment
series.
Few researchers including Barkoulas, Filizetkin, and Murphy (1996),
Jansen and Schulze (1996), Taylor (1996), and Miller (1988) have
examined the relationship between saving and investment using
cointegration techniques. Again, these authors focused mainly on the
OECD countries. As a contribution to the literature, the current study
employs cointegration-based techniques to extend the saving-investment
debate to the ASEAN countries. Such an analysis is worthwhile given that
the economic experiences of the ASEAN countries are arguably very
different from those of OECD countries. Notably, the ASEAN economies are
often plagued with inefficient public enterprises, deficient infrastructure, tight trade controls, restrictive regulations in the
financial sector, poor corporate governance and political uncertainty.
Under these conditions, the macroeconomic dynamics that govern the
relationship between savings and investment in developing countries
could be very different from those that are witnessed in the OECD gro up
of countries.
The selection of the ASEAN countries also deserves justification
from another perspective. It has been documented that East Asian
countries including, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore,
and Thailand have experienced high saving and investment rates. Table 1
indicates that between 1960 and 1996, saving as a percentage of gross
domestic product (GDP) increased in all of the countries under
consideration with the exception of the Philippines. Similarly, Table 2
reveals that gross domestic investment as a ratio of GDP increased in
all of the sample countries. A number of explanations have been advanced
in the literature in relation to this phenomenon. Adams and Prazmowski
(1996) explain the high saving and investment rates for the region in
the context of virtuous cycle. According to the authors, increases in
saving and investment engender economic growth, which in turn, leads to
increases in domestic saving and investment. World Bank (1993) reports
that most of the East Asian countries restricted the outflow of capital
during the periods of their high economic growth in order to encourage
domestic investment. However, it is important to point out that most of
the financial markets in the region were liberalized beginning in the
early 1970s to late 1980s. In light of these characteristics, the sample
countries provide estimable avenues to explore the long-run equilibrium
relationship between saving and investment.
Following the present introduction to the paper, section 2 examines
the data and methodology of the study. Section 3 discusses the empirical
results. Finally, section 4 summarizes the findings of the study.
2. DATA AND METHODOLOGY
The study utilizes annual data on gross domestic saving and
investment for Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, and
Thailand. The data cover the period 1960 through 1996. All the data are
collected from the World Bank, World Development Indicators 1998.
In conducting cointegration tests, the time series are required to
be nonstationary in their levels. Moreover, it is important that all
time series in the cointegrating equation have the same order of
integration. Consequently, the study first ascertains the time series
properties of domestic saving and investment by employing both the DF
and ADF tests for stationarity. The equation estimated for the ADF test
takes the form: [2]
[delta][X.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][X.sub.t-1] +
[delta]t + [[[sigma].sup.m].sub.i=1][[theta].sub.i][delta][X.sub.t-1] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (1)
where, [delta] is the first-difference operator, t is the time
trend, and [epsilon] is the stationary random error, and m is the
maximum lag length.
To determine whether saving and investment are cointegrated, the
Johansen cointegration procedure is utilized [see Johansen (1991) and
Johansen and Juselius (1990)]. The procedure involves the estimation of
VECM in order to obtain the likelihoodratios (LR). The VECM used for
cointegration is as follows:
[delta][Y.sub.t] = [[theta].sub.0] +
[[[sigma].sup.k=1].sub.i=1][delta][Y.sub.t-i] +
[alpha][beta]'[Y.sub.t-k] + [[epsilon].sub.t] (2)
where [delta] is the difference operator, [delta][Y.sub.t] is
([delta][GDS.sub.t], [delta][GDI.sub.t]), [[theta].sub.0] represents the
intercept, and [epsilon] represents the vector of white noise process.
The matrix [beta] consists of r (r [less than or equal to] n -1)
cointegrating vectors. On the other hand, the matrix [alpha] contains
the error-correction parameters. In equation (2), the null hypothesis is
that the matrix (II = [alpha][beta]') has a reduced rank of r [less
than or equal to] n - 1. The alternative hypothesis, on the other hand,
is that the matrix (II = [alpha][beta]') has full rank. [3]
Johansen procedure of cointegration provides two statistics. These
include the value of the LR test based on the maximum eigenvalue of the
stochastic matrix and the value of the LR test based on the trace of the
stochastic matrix. Under the trace test, the null hypothesis is that II
has zero rank (r = 0) and the alternate hypothesis is that r [less than
or equal to] 1. However, the null hypothesis for the maximum eigenvalue
test is that r = 1 while the alternate hypothesis is that r = 2. The
existence of at least one cointegrating vector in the system indicates
the presence of causality between saving and investment.
The causal relationship between gross saving and investment is
explored with Granger-causality test based on VECM. This procedure is
particularly attractive over the standard VAR because it permits
temporary causality to emanate from (1) the sum of the lagged
coefficients of the explanatory differenced variables and (2) the
coefficient of the lagged error-correction term. In addition, the VECM
allows causality to emerge even if the lagged differences of the
explanatory variables are not jointly significant [see Granger (1988),
Miller and Russek (1990), Miller (1991), and Garcia and Zapata (1991)].
It must be pointed out that the standard Granger-causality test omits
the additional channel of influence ([z.sub.t-1]) In this study, the
causality tests are based on the following VECM:
[delta][X.sub.t] = [alpha][z.sub.t-1] +
[[[sigma].sup.a].sub.i=1][[beta].sub.i][delta][X.sub.t-i] +
[[[sigma].sup.b].sub.j=1][[phi].sub.j][delta][Y.sub.t-1] +
[[micro].sub.t] (3)
[delta][Y.sub.t] = [varphi][z.sub.t-1] +
[[[sigma].sup.c].sub.i=1][[theta].sub.i][delta][Y.sub.t-1] +
[[[sigma].sup.d].sub.j=1][[lambda].sub.j][delta][X.sub.t-1] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (4)
where, [z.sub.t-1] represents the error correction term lagged by
one period, [4] X is the gross domestic saving (GDS) as a ratio of GDP,
Y stands for gross domestic investment (GDI) scaled by GDP, a, b, c, and
d represent the optimal lag lengths obtained from the Akaike Information
Criterion (AIC). In equation (3) the rejection of the null hypothesis
that gross domestic investment does not Granger-cause saving requires
that (i) the [phi]j's conjointly be statistically significant
and/or (ii) the error correction term ([z.sub.t-1]) be statistically
significant. Similarly, in equation (4) the null hypothesis that gross
domestic saving does not cause investment is rejected provided that the
[lambda]j's are jointly statistically significant and/or the
error-correction term ([z.sub.t-1]) is significant.
3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The results of both the Dickey-Fuller (DF) and the augmented
Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit root tests are presented in Table 3. The null
hypothesis of nonstationarity of saving and investment is tested against
the alternative hypothesis of stationarity. The results indicate that
both saving and investment are not stationary in their levels. However,
after first differencing, the null hypothesis of no unit root is
rejected in all of the cases. In all, the results indicate one order of
integration [I(1)] for saving and investment series. The nonstationarity
of the time series in their levels calls for the application of
cointegration procedure to avoid the problem of spurious regression.
Having determined the order of integration, we next apply the
Johansen procedure to ascertain whether investment and saving are
cointegrated for each of the countries under consideration. The results
of the Johansen cointegration tests are presented in Table 4. The null
hypothesis of no cointegration between saving and investment (i.e. r =
0) is rejected by both the trace and maximal eigenvalue
([[lambda].sub.max]) tests at the 5 percent significance level in all of
the cases. Nevertheless, the null hypothesis that r [less than or equal
to] 1 could not be rejected for all of the sample countries. The fact
that saving and investment are found to be cointegrated suggests that
capital is immobile internationally relative to the sample countries.
This finding that investment and saving are cointegrated, although
suggestive, is consistent with Feldstein and Horioka (1980), Caprio and
Howard (1984), Feldstein and Bacchetta (1989), Baxter and Crucini
(1993), and Dooley, Frankel, and Mathieson (1987).
The results for the error-correction based Granger-causality tests
are presented in Table 5. These tests are conducted with residuals from
the cointegration equations. The results indicate that for Indonesia and
Singapore, causality runs from investment to saving. The null hypothesis
that investment does not Granger-cause saving is rejected because the
error-correction terms are statistically significant for these
countries. This finding implicates the error-correction terms as the
only channel of influence since the lagged differences of saving are not
conjointly significant. In the case of the Philippines, the null
hypothesis that saving does not cause investment is rejected since the
error-correction term is significant. Again, the error-correction term
emerges as the sole channel of influence. For Malaysia and Thailand, the
results in Table 5 show that causality runs from saving to investment
and vice versa. Specifically, a bi-directional causality is detected
between the two series. In the case of Malays ia, causality emerges from
both the significant error-correction terms and the lagged differences
of domestic investment. Again, for Thailand, the two channels of
causality are present. We observe in Table 5 that the error-correction
term is statistically significant relative to equation (2). Similarly,
the lagged differences of gross domestic saving and investment are
statistically significant.
[delta][GDS.sub.t] = [alpha][z.sub.t-1] +
[[[sigma].sup.a].sub.i=1][[beta].sub.i][delta][GDS.sub.t-i] +
[[[sigma].sup.b].sub.j=1][[phi].sub.j][delta][GDI.sub.t-1] +
[[micro].sub.t]
[delta][GDI.sub.t] = [xi][z.sub.t-1] +
[[[sigma].sup.c].sub.i=1][V.sub.i][delta][GDI.sub.t-1] +
[[[sigma].sup.d].sub.j=1][[lambda].sub.j][delta][GDS.sub.t-1] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]
where [z.sub.t-1] represents the error-correction term lagged by
one period, GDS is the ratio of gross domestic savings to GDP, GDI is
the ratio of gross domestic investment to GDP, a, b, c, and d represent
the optimal lag lengths determined by Akaike Information Criterion. The
level of significance for the error-correction terms ([z.sub.t-1]) is
determined by the standard t-statistics.
4. CONCLUSIONS
This paper has used cointegration procedure to examine the long-run
equilibrium relationship between saving and investment in the ASEAN
countries namely--Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand.
Consistent with a number of earlier studies in the literature, saving
and investment are found to be cointegrated in the long run for all of
the countries under consideration. The conclusion that saving and
investment are cointegrated implies that there is a strong internal
association between the two series. Simply, the results indicate that
long-term capital is not mobile internationally for all of the countries
under study. Furthermore, the error-correction based Granger-causality
tests indicate that causality runs from investment to saving for
Indonesia and Singapore. For the Philippines, a unidirectional causality
from saving to investment was found. Finally, in the cases of Malaysia
and Thailand, causality runs in both directions.
Although this paper has established the existence of long-run
relationship between saving and investment for the countries under
study, there is still room for further research. Interest rate could be
included as a mediating variable in the examination of the long-run
relationship between saving and investment. The inclusion of interest
rate will alleviate the possibility of distortion of causality
inferences resulting from the omission of a relevant variable.
(*.) Department of Management Science and Economics, Coppin State
College, Baltimore, Maryland 21216-3698. The author is grateful to
Sanjay Ramchander, Habtu Braha, and an anonymous referee for their
invaluable comments and suggestions that helped to improve the quality
of this paper. The author assumes full responsibility for all errors in
this study.
Notes
(1.) Furthermore, Granger and Newbold (1974) and Engle and Granger
(1987) have demonstrated that the use of cointegration technique avoids
spurious regression results.
(2.) For standard DF unit root test, we exclude the summation from
the right hand side of equation (1).
(3.) In the present study, full rank would imply that r is equal to
2, since saving and investment are the only two time series in the
model.
(4.) The cointegration equation used in this study is as follows:
[y.sub.t] = [alpha][x.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t], where, [y.sub.t] and
[x.sub.t] each represents GDS and GDI.
References
Adams, F. G. and P. Prazmowski (1996) "Why Are Saving Rates in
East Asia So High? Reviving the Life Cycle Hypothesis." Economics
Research Unit: University of Pennsylvania: Philadelphia.
Barkoulas, John, Alpay Filizetkin and Robert Murphy (1996),
"Time Series Evidence On the Saving-Investment Relationship,"
Applied Economics Letters, 3, 77-80.
Baxter, Marianne and Mario Crucini (1993) "Explaining
Saving-Investment Correlations," American Economic Review, 83,
416-436.
Bayoumi, Tamin (1990), "Saving-Investment Corrections:
Immobile Capital, Government Policy, or Endogenous Behavior?" IMF Staff Papers, 27, 360-387.
Caprio, Gerald, Jr. and David H. Howard (1984) "Domestic
Saving, Current Accounts, and International Capital Mobility,"
International Finance Discussion Paper 244 (Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System).
Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller (1979) "Distribution of
Estimates of Autoregressive Time Series With Unit Root," Journal of
the American Statistical Association, 427-431.
Dooley, Michael, Jeffrey Frankel, and Donald Mathieson (1987),
"International Capital Mobility in Developing Countries versus
Industrialized Countries: What Do Savings-Investment Correlations Tell
Us?" IMF Staff Papers, 34, 503-529.
Engle, R. F. and Granger, C. W. J. (1987), "Cointegration and
Error Correction: Estimation and Testing," Econometrica, 55,
251-276.
Feldstein, Martin and Charles Horioka (1980), "Domestic Saving
and International Capital Flows," Economic Journal, 90, 314-329.
Feldstein, Martin (1983), "Domestic Saving and International
Capital Rows," European Economic Review, 21, 129-151.
----- and Baccheta (1989) "National Saving and International
Investment," NBER Working Paper 3164 (Cambridge, Massachusetts:
National Bureau of Economic Research, November).
Finn, Mary G. (1990), "On Saving and Investment Dynamics in a
Small Open Economy," Journal of International Economics, 29, 1-21.
Garcia, Philip and Hector Zapata (1991), "Co-integration,
Error-correction and the Fisher effect: A Clarification" Applied
Economics, 23, 1367-1368.
Granger, Clive W. J. (1969) "Investigating Causal Relations by
Econometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods" Econometrica, 37,
424-438.
----- (1983) "Co-Integrated Variables and Error-Correcting
Models." Working Paper 83-13. University of California, San Diego.
----- (1988) "Some Recent Developments in a Concept of
Causality" Journal of Econometrics, 39, 199-211.
----- and P. Newbold (1974) "Spurious Regression in
Econometrics," Journal of Econometrics, 34,111-120.
Jansen, W. J. and G. G. Schulze (1996) "Theory--Based
Measurement of the Saving Investment Correlation with an Application to
Norway." Economic Inquiry, 34, 116-132.
Johansen, S. (1991) "Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models,"
Econometrica, 59, 1551-1580.
----- and K. Juselius (1990) "Maximum Likelihood Estimation
and Inference on Cointegration--with Applications to the Demand for
Money," Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52, 169-210.
Miller, Stephen (1988) "Are Saving and Investment
Cointegrated?" 27, 31-34.
----- (1991) "Monetary Dynamics: An Application of
Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling," Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, 23, 139-154.
Miller, Stephen and Frank S. Russek (1990) "Cointegration and
Error-Correction Models: The Temporal Causality between Government Taxes
and Spending," Southern Economic Journal, 221-229.
Murphy, Robert, G. (1984) "Capital Mobility and the
Relationship between Saving and Investment in OECD Countries,"
Journal of International Money and Finance, 10, 327-342
Nelson, C. R. and C. I. Plosser (1982) "Trends and Random
Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Some Evidence and
Implications," Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, 139-162.
Obstfeld, Maurice (1986) "Capital Mobility in the World
Economy: Theory and Measurement," Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, Spring, 24, 55-104.
Stockman, Allen C. and Linda Tesar L. (1991) "Tastes and
Technology in a Two-Country Model of the Business Cycle: Explaining
International Co-movements," Rochester Center for Economic Research
Working Paper No. 255, University of Rochester.
Summers, Lawrence H. (1988) "Tax Policy and International
Competitiveness," in J. Frenkel, ed., International Aspect of
Fiscal Policies, Chicago: University of Chicago press, 349-375.
Taylor, Alan M. (1996) "International Capital Mobility in
History: The Saving-Investment Relationship," NBER Working Paper
5743 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research,
September).
Tesar, Linda L. (1991) "Savings, Investment and International
Capital Flows," Journal of International Economics, 31, 55-78.
World Bank (1993) "The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and
Public Policy" New York: Oxford.
Gross Domestic Saving (as % of GDP)
Country 1960-1970 1970-1980 1980-1990 1990-1995 1996
Indonesia 8.55 26.16 30.82 32.26 33.15
Malaysia 24.11 30.02 33.34 35.72 41.90
Philippines 18.84 24.83 20.73 16.62 14.40
Singapore -1.90 29.42 41.97 47.56 50.47
Thailand 18.88 22.31 27.11 35.57 35.31
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 1998.
Domestic Investment (as % of GDP)
Country 1960-1970 1970-1980 1980-1990 1990-1995 1996
Indonesia 10.30 21.85 27.20 29.75 31.83
Malaysia 19.45 25.92 30.81 36.47 41.24
Philippines 19.71 27.19 22.64 22.66 24.19
Singapore 21.50 41.00 41.65 34.93 35.07
Thailand 20.98 26.11 30.50 41.28 41.00
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 1998.
Unit Root Tests (1960-1996)
Country/ DF
Period Series Level
Indonesia
1960-1996 GDS [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.61
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.64
GDI [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.98
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.91
Malaysia
1960-1996 GDS [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.70
[T.sub.[tau]] = -2.03
GDI [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.83
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.96
Philippines
1960-1996 GDS [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.17
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.79
GDI [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.67
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.67
Singapore
1960-1996 GDS [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.90
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.90
GDI [T.sub.[micro]] = -2.22
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.80
Thailand
1960-1996 GDS [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.69
[T.sub.[tau]] = -1.92
GDI [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.88
[T.sub.[tau]] = -2.13
Country/ ADF
Period Difference Level
Indonesia
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -6.70 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.64
[T.sub.[tau]] = -7.63 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -1.54
[T.sub.[micro]] = -5.98 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -2.17
[T.sub.[tau]] = -6.78 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -1.76
Malaysia
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -7.02 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.71
[T.sub.[tau]] = -6.89 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -2.47
[T.sub.[micro]] = -4.27 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.21
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.20 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -3.06
Philippines
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -7.40 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.54
[T.sub.[tau]] = -7.59 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -1.18
[T.sub.[micro]] = -4.16 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -2.22
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.10 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -2.19
Singapore
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -4.26 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -1.46
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.30 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -1.68
[T.sub.[micro]] = -4.77 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -2.27
[T.sub.[tau]] = -5.18 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -1.83
Thailand
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -7.79 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.26
[T.sub.[tau]] = -7.91 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -1.42
[T.sub.[micro]] = -5.50 [**] [T.sub.[micro]] = -0.84
[T.sub.[tau]] = -5.45 [**] [T.sub.[tau]] = -2.19
Country/
Period Difference Lag Order
Indonesia
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -4.13 [**] 2
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.85 [**] 2
[T.sub.[micro]] = -3.62 [**] 2
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.33 [**] 2
Malaysia
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -4.40 [**] 2
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.29 [**] 2
[T.sub.[micro]] = -3.82 [**] 4
[T.sub.[tau]] = -3.78 [**] 4
Philippines
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -4.45 [**] 1
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.72 [**] 1
[T.sub.[micro]] = -4.48 [**] 1
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.42 [**] 1
Singapore
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -4.14 [**] 1
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.31 [**] 1
[T.sub.[micro]] = -2.96 [**] 1
[T.sub.[tau]] = -3.25 [**] 1
Thailand
1960-1996 [T.sub.[micro]] = -3.77 [**] 2
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.02 [**] 2
[T.sub.[micro]] = -4.22 [**] 2
[T.sub.[tau]] = -4.20 [**] 2
(*.)and (**.)10 and 5 percent significance levels, respectively.
[T.sub.[micro]] = without trend. DF Dickey-Fuller statistic, ADF =
augmented Dickey-Fuller statistic, [T.sub.[tau]] = with trend. GDS =
ratio of gross domestic savings to GDP and GDI = ratio of gross domestic
investment to GDP. The critical values at the 5% level of significance
are -2.96 and -3.57, respectively for without trend and with trend. The
10% critical values for without trend and with trend are -2.26 and
-3.20, respectively. The lag orders are determined by Akaike Information
Criterion (AIC).
Johansen Cointegration Test Results
Null: r = 0
Country Trace [[lambda].sub.max]
Indonesia 26.86 [**] 21.66 [**]
Malaysia 25.42 [**] 20.66 [**]
Philippines 71.11 [**] 67.42 [**]
Singapore 34.80 [**] 31.50 [**]
Thailand 30.92 [**] 24.69 [**]
Null: r
[less than or equal to] 1
Country Trace [[lambda].sub.max]
Indonesia 5.20 5.20
Malaysia 4.76 4.76
Philippines 3.69 3.69
Singapore 3.30 3.30
Thailand 6.23 6.23
(**.)indicates the rejection of the null hypothesis at the 5%
significance level. The critical values for the trace test hypotheses r
[less than or equal to] 1 and r [less than or equal to] 0 are 11.54 and
18.33 respectively. The critical values for the [[lambda].sub.max] test
hypotheses r [less than or equal to] 1 and r [less than or equal to] 0
are 11.54 and 23.83 respectively. The critical values are obtained from
the Microfit 4.0 program.
F-Statistics for Bivariate Causality
Tests Based on VECM
Indonesia Malayasia
Panel A: Saving Equation ([delta]GDS)
[z.sub.t-1] 9.13 [*] 5.04 [*]
[sigma][delta]GDI 1.86 6.34 [*]
Panel B: investment Equation ([delta]GDI)
[z.sub.t-1] 0.08 7.47 [*]
[sigma][delta]GDS 0.23 1.58
Philippines Singapore
Panel A: Saving Equation ([delta]GDS)
[z.sub.t-1] 0.56 7.79 [*]
[sigma][delta]GDI 1.21 0.18
Panel B: investment Equation ([delta]GDI)
[z.sub.t-1] 7.12 [*] 0.12
[sigma][delta]GDS 1.88 0.13
Thailand
Panel A: Saving Equation ([delta]GDS)
[z.sub.t-1] 0.42
[sigma][delta]GDI 3.12 [**]
Panel B: investment Equation ([delta]GDI)
[z.sub.t-1] 15.38 [*]
[sigma][delta]GDS 2.73 [***]
(*.), (**.), and (***.)represent rejection
of the hypotheses at 1%, 5%, and 10% level
of significance. The estimated error-
correction models are as follows: