Rice, Salmon Or Sushi? Political competition for supply of a regulated input.
Kahane, Leo H.
The early work by Olson (1965) and Tullock (1967) on the political
competition for economic rents has fostered a growing body of literature
devoted to the study of pressure group influence on public policy. For
example rent-seeking behavior, with a focus on the degree of rent
dissipation, has been examined by a variety of researchers including
Bhagwati (1987); Hillman and Samet (1987); Varian (1989). Others,
including Becker (1983); Findlay and Wellisz (1982, 1983); Nitzan
(1991), have emphasized the nature of competition among pressure groups
for political influence. This paper continues along this latter line of
research by developing a simple, game-theoretic model which describes
how rival groups politically compete for the supply of a government
regulated input. Of particular interest in this study is the effects of
the degree of internal lobby group organization on a group's
ability to effectively compete for the regulated input. It should be
acknowledged that given the hypothetical nature of the model d escribed
below, (and the lack of relevant data to test the model), its primary
function is pedagogical. That is, the goal of this paper is to provide
an interesting example of how models of endogenous policy formation can
applied to a variety of interesting policy issues.
As a means of motivating the model described below, an example of
the on-going struggle for government controlled water in California will
be used. The six years of drought in California from the mid-1980s to
1992 left water reserves at their lowest level since 1977. This scarcity of water intensified the struggle between competing users of
government-controlled water supplies. (1) For example rice and salmon
production depend heavily on the availability of water; for any given
level of water, the larger the proportion of water rice growers receive,
the less salmon farmers receive. This resulting conflict between rice
growers and salmon farmers gives rise to an interesting model for policy
formation. Notwithstanding the fact that these two products are quite
diverse and do not compete in the goods market, rice growers and salmon
farmers do compete in a political market for water rights. If the
government (which has control over water rights) is responsive to
political lobby pressure, then water rights may be endogenous to the
lobby activities of groups that stand to gain or lose from a particular
water distribution policy. In such a framework, an interesting question
arises as to the effects on the lobbying process of differing degrees of
lobby group organization or coordination. That is, if say rice growers
come together and determine their optimal level of lobby expenditure
(given some level of lobby expenditure by salmon farmers), how does this
level of expenditure compare to the case when individual rice growers do
not come together but act alone to lobby the government? The model
presented below captures the effects of different degrees of lobby group
organization by developing a simple n-firm Cournot model with endogenous
policy formation.
The remainder of this paper is organized into three sections. The
first section develops the above mentioned model of endogenous policy
formation. An equilibrium involving optimal quantities of output and
lobby contributions for individual group members is described. The next
section examines the effects on optimal lobby contributions of different
conjectures about internal lobby group organization. The last section
contains concluding remarks.
1. The Model
To examine the importance of internal lobby group organization,
suppose there is a continuous policy measure, m, that is being
considered by local political leaders. We can assume that there are two
groups of producers, rice growers and salmon farmers, in the locality
which do not compete in the goods market but are both affected by the
measure. In particular, if we let m be the amount of government
controlled water allotted to rice production, then rice growers favor a
larger m because it reduces the marginal cost of rice production. On the
other hand, salmon farmers prefer a smaller m since less water for rice
farmers means more water for salmon farming which will decrease their
marginal cost of production. Assume that both the rice growing sector
and salmon farming sector are n-firm Cournot oligopolies producing a
homogeneous good (internally) and that within each group members are
identical in size and have the same production technology. It is assumed
internally that each group acts collectively on the political front but
competitively in the goods market. The key element for this analysis
then will be how groups fare under different conjectures regarding
internal lobby group organization.
It is assumed that both groups are able to contribute lobbying
funds in an effort to influence the outcome of the decision by local
politicians on the level of m chosen. (2) Suppose that each group
believes that the level of m chosen by the government is determined by
the following policy formation function: (3)
M = m(L, L')
where: L = [summation over (n/i=1)] [L.sub.i] L' = [summation
over (n'/,j=1)] [L.sub.j]
and [partial]m/[partial]L > 0,
[[partial].sup.2]m/[partial][L.sup.2] <, [partial]m/[partial]L'
< 0, [[partial].sup.2]m/[partial][L'.sup.2] < 0 (1.1)
Where L and L' are the total contributions by rice growers and
salmon farmers, respectively, to the lobbying effort.
Let the rice grower's market demand curve have the following
simple linear form:
P(Q) = a - bQ
with: Q = [summation over (n/i=1)][q.sub.i] (1.2)
where Q represents the industry output and [q.sub.i] the ith
individual producer's output. For simplicity we will assume that
there are no fixed costs of production. Given the above industry demand
function, we can now write the profit function of an individual rice
grower as:
[[pi].sub.i] = P(Q)[q.sub.i] - [kq.sub.i] - [L.sub.i] (1.3)
where k is the marginal cost to production and [L.sub.i] is the ith
individual producer's contribution to the lobbying effort. As was
described above, the policy measure m is assumed to reduce the marginal
cost of production for rice farmers. To this end let marginal cost for
rice farmers be determined by the following simple function:
k = (c - m) (1.4)
where c is constant with respect to output.
We can now use equation (1.1) and (1.4) to rewrite the profit
function in (1.3) as:
[[pi].sub.i] = (a - bQ)[q.sub.i] - (c - m)[q.sub.i] - [L.sub.i]
(1.5)
In order to maximize equation (1.5) with respect to [q.sub.i] and
[L.sub.i] it is necessary to make an assumption on how individuals view
the behavior of the salmon farmers' group when members of the rice
growers' group choose output quantities and lobby expenditures. (4)
To this end, a Nash assumption is adopted meaning that individuals in
the rice growers group take the level of contributions by salmon growers
as given when choosing their optimal contribution level.
In maximizing (1.5) it will be assumed that individual rice growers
first choose a level of contributions [L.sub.i]. Given this level of
contributions, the rice growers then choose output levels, [q.sub.i].
Under this assumption, we can solve the model first for optimal output
levels. Doing so yields the following:
[q.sup.*.sub.i] = (a - c + m)/b(n + 1) (1.6)
Equation (1.6) resembles the familiar n-firm Cournot solution for
optimal quantities, but is augmented by the effect of m on the marginal
cost of production. (5) Having solved for optimal output levels for
firms, the result shown in equation (1.6) can now be substituted into
the profit function in (1.5) giving the reduced profit function below:
[[pi].sub.i] = [(a - c + m).sup.2] / b[(n+1).sup.2] - [L.sub.i]
(1.7)
The reduced form profit function shown in equation (1.7) would now
be maximized with respect to contribution levels [L.sub.i]. Before
carrying out this step however, more information is required. In
particular, individuals in the rice growers' group must form a
conjecture regarding how members within their group behave. That is, the
policy on water distribution represented by m has a collective good
character in that all rice farmers gain from a higher m whether or not
they contribute to the lobbying effort and thus a free rider problem emerges. As such, how the rice growers organize themselves becomes an
important issue. Before dealing with this issue we can, however, make
several observations regarding the profit function shown in (1.7). The
first part on the right hand side of (1.7) represents the gross profits
for any individual given [q.sub.i] and contribution level [L.sub.i]. The
second part, [L.sub.i], is simply the cost of that lobby contribution
level which is assumed to be linear in [L.sub.i]. (6) T aken together
the right hand side then gives profits net of lobby expenditures. Note
that given the assumptions on the policy formation function given in
(1.1), gross profits will be a monotonically increasing, concave
function in [L.sub.i]. (7) The graph shown in Figure 1 gives an example
of these functions for a given level of contributions by salmon farmers.
The gap between the gross profit curve and the cost of contribution line
represents net profits. The profit maximizing level of contributions
will be the point at which the gap between the two functions is the
widest or, in other words, where the marginal gross profit is equal to
the marginal cost of contributing. Assuming symmetry across groups we
can also determine salmon farmers' optimal output levels and lobby
contributions, for a given level of contributions by rice growers.
The graph for rice growers was drawn for a given level of
contributions by salmon farmers. If the level of contributions by salmon
farmers changes, then this would give rise to a new gross profit
function and equilibrium contribution level for rice growers. Thus the
optimum contribution level for rice growers, [L.sub.i], is a function of
total contributions of salmon farmers, which in turn is a function of
individual salmon farmers' contributions, [L'.sub.i]. And
conversely, optimal [L'.sub.i] is a function of [L.sub.i]. In other
words, we have two reaction functions represented as follows:
[L.sub.i] = R([L'.sub.i])
and
[L'.sub.i] = R'([L.sub.i]) (1.8)
Finding equilibrium individual contribution levels for both groups
involves solving both the above reaction functions simultaneously for
[L.sub.i] and [L'.sub.i]. (8) In order to ensure an equilibrium
exists, it is assumed that the slopes of the reaction functions are
positive and less than one with respect to their arguments. (9) That is,
in the case for rice growers, if an individual salmon farmer increases
their contributions by 1 unit, an individual rice grower is assumed to
increase their contributions but by less than 1 unit. (10) Examples of
reaction functions satisfying the assumptions listed above are shown in
Figure 2.
The intersection of two reaction functions gives equilibrium
contribution levels for individual rice growers and salmon farmers.
Notice also that, given the specification of the policy formation
function in (1.1), there are "iso-policy" curves such as
[m.sup.1] - [m.sup.1] in Figure 2 which represent the same policy
outcome ([m.sup.1] for various combinations of [L.sub.i] and
[L.sub.i]'.
2. Optimal Lobby Contributions and Lobby Group Coordination
The model above describes an equilibrium in lobby group
contributions. As was mentioned in the introduction of this paper, one
of the interesting issues relating to lobby group confrontation is the
effects of group organization or coordination. This section analyzes the
effects on optimal lobby group contributions and profits of individual
rice growers and salmon farmers of different conjectures over internal
lobby group organization.
The degree of internal lobby group coordination can be captured in
the above model by looking more closely at equation (1.1), the policy
formation function. Consider individual rice growers who choose their
contribution [L.sub.i] so as to maximize profits represented by equation
(1.7). When taking the partial derivative of the gross profit with
respect to [L.sub.i] we obtain the following result:
[partial][[pi].sub.gross]/[partial][L.sub.i] = 2(a - c + m)/b[(n +
1).sup.2] [partial]m/[partial]L [partial]L/[partial][L.sub.i] (2.1)
The final factor on the right hand side of equation (2.1), the
partial derivative of total lobby group contributions with respect to
individual contributions, represents the individual's behavioral
conjecture for internal lobby group organization. That is, it represents
what the individual contributor believes will be the response from
fellow group members to an increase in their contribution level. We can
consider two extreme cases for this conjecture. If the individual holds
a Nash conjecture, meaning that when they consider optimal contribution
levels it is believed that other group members will not change their
contribution levels, then the final term on equation (2.1) will be:
[partial]L/[partial][L.sub.i] = 1 (2.2)
We can compare this conjecture to one where lobby groups are
perfectly coordinated, by perhaps a planner, and determine optimal
contributions for the group as a whole which is then divided across all
individual members. Under this scenario, the final term for equation
(2.1) would be:
[partial]L/[partial][L.sub.i] = n (2.3)
where n represents the number of individuals in the group. The
qualitative effects of these two conjectures in terms of optimal
contributions for individuals can be determined by referring back to
equation (2.1) and noting that the slope of the gross profit function is
increasing in the conjecture for group organization. That is, the slope
of gross profit function will be steeper under perfect lobby group
coordination than it would be under the Nash conjecture. Thus, as Figure
3 shows, for any given level of contributions by salmon farmers, optimal
level of individual contributions and profits for rice growers are
greater under the case of perfect lobby group coordination (denoted by
P) than it would be under the Nash case (denoted by N). This result
supports Mancur Olson's (1965) well-known finding that as a group
eliminates free riding it provides itself with more of a collective good
(i.e. m via greater lobby contributions) than it would otherwise.
Furthermore it is easily seen that, all else equal, the di vergence of
equilibrium individual lobby contributions between the Nash and
perfectly organized case increases with n, which is also noted by Olson
(1965).
Maintaining the assumption for the slopes of the reaction functions
made earlier, and starting from the case where both groups are organized
internally under the Nash conjecture the result of rice growers moving
from the Nash conjecture to that of a perfectly coordinated lobby effort
would be to shift up the reaction function for rice growers. This is
shown in Figure 4 (where the subscripts on [L.sub.i] and [L.sub.i]
denote the conjecture for the rice growers and salmon framers,
respectively). The new equilibrium contribution levels for both groups
results in greater contributions by both groups and a new, higher
equilibrium iso-policy [m.sup.2] - [m.sup.2], (where [m.sup.2] >
[m.sup.1]).
If we assume that the two groups are perfectly symmetric (11) an
interesting possibility emerges. Consider the case where both rice
growers and salmon farmers are initially organized under the Nash
conjecture. Suppose then that each group decides to adopt the perfectly
planned conjecture. The result then is a shift upward of the individual
rice grower's reaction function and a similar shift rightward of
individual salmon farmer's reaction function. Given then the
assumption that each group enters the policy formation symmetrically,
the resulting policy m will be the same as when both groups were
organized under the Nash conjecture. This case is shown in Figure 5
where the intersection of the two reaction functions moves along the
same iso-policy curve. The result of this last exercise is that
individuals in both groups are unambiguously worse off with greater
internal lobby group coordination. This is because gross profits have
not changed for any individual since the same level of m prevails in
both cases, b ut each individual member of both groups has expended more
on lobbying. An analogy of this last result can be found in a game of
"tug-of-war." That is, consider two identical but opposing
groups pulling on different ends of a rope. The position of a flag,
which is fastened to the middle of the rope, relative to a point on the
ground could denote the policy measure in. On any one team, individual
members may free ride on the strength of their teammates and hence not
pull as hard as they can, (this would be the Nash case). Thus both teams
would pull weakly on the rope and a particular m results. Each team may
then acquire a volunteer coach who is able to spot, and eliminate free
riding. As a consequence, each team ends up pulling harder on the rope
and, assuming symmetry, the flag remains in the same position as before
when each team pulled weakly. Obviously, in this example all individuals
are worse off with a coach than without since all individuals pull
harder, but gain no ground. (12)
Finally, it is interesting to consider how groups would choose to
organize themselves if they had the opportunity to meet and decide to
adopt a perfectly organized conjecture or not. Under the assumptions
made for this model, and given the discussion for Figure 3 above, each
group member's profit is perceived to increase with greater
coordination in lobbying, given the behavior of the other group. Thus
starting from the case where both groups are internally organized under
the Nash conjecture, each group member believes they can increase their
profits by becoming perfectly coordinated. (13) As such, each group
separately decides to become perfectly organized and as they do so all
individuals are made worse off. In other words, in the case where the
two opposing groups are identical, we get a Prisoner's dilemma
result when each group can choose whether or not to perfectly coordinate
internal lobby activity. Finally, it is interesting to note that from
the policy makers' perspective, if lobbying is in the form of
campaign contributions they would prefer the case where both groups are
perfectly organized since under this scenario lobby contributions are
the greatest.
3. Conclusion
Tullock's (1967) article inspired a great deal of work on
economic models with endogenous policy. (14) There has been very little
said, however, in terms of the effects of free riding in models where
policy is determined endogenously by the confrontation of opposing lobby
groups and it is this issue that was the focus of this paper. (15)
The example used in this paper concerning the conflict over water
rights in California, to be sure, is more complicated than as they are
described above. Indeed, battles over government controlled water from
the Klamath river have involved cattle ranchers, farmers and salmon
growers from both California and Oregon, (who share the Klamath river
waters), as well as the Karuk Indian tribe which depends heavily on the
salmon harvest for their survival. (16) Although the model developed
above is much less complex than this case, it nonetheless presented some
interesting results. It was shown that as a group increased its degree
of internal organization or coordination, it decreased the degree of
free riding by group members and the equilibrium level of contributions
by the group rose. Another interesting finding above was that as two
identical groups intensify their lobby battle against each other by
eliminating free riding in lobby contributions, each can be made worse
off. This result thus expands on Tullock's (1967) argument that
when considering the welfare effects of various economic policies we
must also include in that analysis the deadweight losses due to
unproductive lobbying expenditure. (17)
Possible extensions of the above model are numerous. For example,
one can imagine a more complicated policy formation function where the
government has a more active role in the determination of policy. In
addition, in the above analysis two polar cases for internal lobby group
organization were analyzed: the Nash conjecture and the perfectly
coordinated case. The conjecture for lobby group organization, however,
could also fall anywhere between those two polar cases, and the degree
of lobby group organization itself could in fact be endogenously
determined.
Another extension would be to consider the above model in the
context of a repeated game. In this case the analysis may quickly become
complicated. Repeating the game may affect the equilibrium within each
group as well as across groups and would depend on whether the game is
repeated a finite number of times or if it is repeated infinitely. (18)
One possibility could be that by infinitely repeating the game a
cooperative outcome could prevail which may entail less expenditure on
lobbying.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Notes
(1.) For example, rainfall during the 1994-95 rainy season totaled
nearly 150 percent of the average season rainfall. Nonetheless, many
water users in California were not expected to receive their full
allotment. The reason for the continued shortage was simply that there
were more users than the present water delivery system could handle,
(San Francisco Chronicle, March, 1995: p. 1, 17.)
(2.) Under this assumption the local government behaves in a manner
Bhagwati (1987, p. 3) describes as a "clearing house" where
political officials make decisions on policy solely on the basis of net
lobby group pressure.
(3.) This policy formation function is similar to Findlay and
Wellisz's (1982) tariff formation function which they use in a
model with endogenous tariffs.
(4.) Note that the level of one group's contributions enters
into the other's objective function through m.
(5.) See, for example, Tirole (1989, p. 220). Note that given the
assumption that all individuals are identical, the solution of equation
(1.6) will be the same for all rice growers.
(6.) The units of L are defined such that the cost of each unit is
equal to 1.
(7.) It is assumed that the second derivative of m in (1.1) with
respect to L is sufficiently negative so that this result obtains. If
this condition was not met, optimal lobby contributions could be
infinite.
(8.) Note that given the assumption of symmetry across groups and
that individuals within a group are identical, we can characterize lobby
group behavior by analyzing the behavior of individual members of each
group.
(9.) It is also assumed that in the absence of contributions by one
group there will be a positive optimal level of contributions by the
other group.
(10.) This assumption, of course, need not be the case. In fact,
negatively sloped reaction functions are possible and would lead to
slightly different results.
(11.) "Perfect symmetry" meaning that the two groups are
identical, in terms of size and individual reduced profit functions
(i.e. n = n' and [pi] = [pi]'), yet opposing. It is also
assumed that the marginal effect of a unit of lobby expenditure is
identical, yet opposing. That is,
[partial]m/[partial]L = - [partial]m/[partial]L'
(12.) This of course assumes that individuals do not value the
larger muscles they obtain from pulling harder on the rope.
(13.) Recall the assumption that each group member adopts a Nash
assumption with regard to the behavior of the members of the rival
group.
(14.) See Hillman (1989), for example, for a summary of
international trade models with endogenous commercial policy.
(15.) Findlay and Wellisz (1982, 1983) develop a model where the
action of two opposing lobby groups determine commercial policy, but the
free rider problem is assumed away.
(16.) "Battle for water could be fatal to Klamath
salmon," San Francisco Chronicle, September 8, 1992, p. A13.
(17.) Not addressed in this paper is the possibility of private
property rights to water. It is clear that if private property rights to
water were well defined, enforceable and transferable, water would be
allocated in the most efficient manner since owners of water rights
could auction off water to the highest bidder and in doing so allocate
water to its highest valued use. In the model developed above, the
government could be viewed as auctioning off water rights through the
policy formation function given in equation (1.1). However, if it is
assumed, as it is here, that lobby expenditures aimed at inducing
government policy are not directly productive, then the private market
auction would be more efficient. See Anderson and Leal (1991) for a more
detailed discussion on privatizing water rights.
(18.) If the game is repeated a finite number of times, under given
conjectures for within group organization, then the sub-game perfect
equilibrium across the groups would be the Nash outcome played for each
play of the game, (see Gibbons, 1992, p. 84).
References
Anderson, Terry L. and Donald R. Leal, (1991). "Going With the
Flow: Expanding Water Markets" in Free Market Environmentalism,
Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy, Boulder: Westview Press.
Becker, Gary S., (1983). "A Theory of Competition Among
Pressure Groups for Political Influence," Quarterly Journal of
Economics vol. XCVIII, no. 3:371-400.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N., (1987). "The Theory of Political
Economy, Economic Policy and Foreign Investment," Columbia
University Working Paper No. 386, December.
Findlay, Ronald and Stanislaw Wellisz, (1982). "Endogenous
Tariffs, the Political Economy of Trade Restrictions, and Welfare."
In J. Bhagwati, ed., Import Competition and Response. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
----- and -----, (1983), "Some Aspects of the Political
Economy of Trade Restrictions," Kyklos 36, 469-483.
Gibbons, Robert (1992), Game Theory for Applied Economists,
Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press
Hillman, Arye L., (1989). The Political Economy of Protectionism,
Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers.
Hillman, Arye L. and D. Samet, (1987). "Dissipation of Rents
and Revenues in Small Number Contests," Public Choice vol. 54,
63-82.
Olson, Mancur, (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods
and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Nitzan, Shmuel, (1991). "Collective Rent Dissipation,"
Economic Journal 101, 1522-1534.
Tirole, Jean, (1989). The Theory of Industrial Organization.
Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press.
Tullock, Gordon, (1967). "The Welfare Costs to Tariffs,
Monopolies and Theft." Western Economic Journal 5, 224-232.
Varian, H.R., (1989). "Measuring the Deadweight Costs of DUP and Rent Seeking Activities," Economics and Politics vol. 1, 81-95.
Leo H. Kahane *
* California State University, Hayward, CA 94542, (510) 885-3369,
(510) 885-2923 (fax),
[email protected]