首页    期刊浏览 2025年05月03日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The development of water rights in Colorado: an empirical analysis.
  • 作者:Penn, David A. ; Zietz, Joachim
  • 期刊名称:American Economist
  • 印刷版ISSN:0569-4345
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:September
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Omicron Delta Epsilon
  • 摘要:An important insight offered by the property rights economics literature is that institutions, or the rules of the game, affect how well markets function (Pejovich 1990). Properly functioning markets require well-defined and enforceable property rights. When property rights are poorly defined or weakly enforced, market incentives that encourage entrepreneurial activity, innovation and invention, creative activity, and hard work will diminish in effectiveness (Demsetz 1967).
  • 关键词:Property rights;Right of property;United States economic conditions;Water;Water rights

The development of water rights in Colorado: an empirical analysis.


Penn, David A. ; Zietz, Joachim


I. Introduction

An important insight offered by the property rights economics literature is that institutions, or the rules of the game, affect how well markets function (Pejovich 1990). Properly functioning markets require well-defined and enforceable property rights. When property rights are poorly defined or weakly enforced, market incentives that encourage entrepreneurial activity, innovation and invention, creative activity, and hard work will diminish in effectiveness (Demsetz 1967).

Property rights do not spring up from the ground well defined and enforceable. Rather. they change over time due, in part, to changing economic circumstances (Demsetz 1967; Anderson 1982; Pejovich 1990). People not only pursue their self-interest within the rules, they also allocate resources to changing the rules of the game to their own benefit (Anderson 1982, p. 761). In fact, establishing and protecting property rights can be considered a productive activity toward which resources will be devoted.

The manner in which certain property rights emerge and change over time is the focus of this study. The origins and evolution of Western water law offer an important example of how property rights change in response to changing economic incentives. The paper focuses on the Colorado experience largely due to the fact that Colorado was one of the first states to establish a system of water rights based exclusively on the system of prior appropriation. Many of the developments in water rights in the rest of the Western United States derive in one way or another from the Colorado system.

Our study offers the first quantitative evidence that links economic incentives with water rights defining and enforcing activity. Our model suggests that water claimants will more carefully define their rights to water when either the demand for water increases or the supply of water decreases. The results also indicate that not all empirical facts easily match a theory of property rights evolution, as developed, for example, in Anderson (1982). To understand historical developments it appears useful to also incorporate the predictions of the rent seeking literature (e.g., Krueger 1974), especially as it applies to agriculture (Honma and Hayami 1986; Anderson and Hayami 1987; Gardner 1987).

The manner in which water rights evolve and adapt to increasing demand for water and frequent periods of scarcity is at least as relevant today as it was in the late 19th century. Rapidly rising demand coupled with periodic severe droughts exert great pressure on today's water allocation institutions, in the U.S. as in other countries. Competition for water has multiplied for a number of reasons including rapid urban population growth, protection of instream water rights, competition for water among states, and the recognition of Native American water rights.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section provides a brief account of water rights development in Colorado, offering qualitative evidence of how the rules of the game evolve with changing economic circumstances. This is followed by an outline of a simple model for water rights development. The data are presented next, followed with a presentation of empirical model estimates. The paper ends with a brief summary and some conclusions.

II. Historical and Legal Background

Agricultural development, irrigation, and the evolution of water rights law were inseparably linked during the late 19th and early 20th centuries in Colorado. The next section discusses the historical development of irrigation in Colorado, followed with an analysis of the formation of legal precedents.

1. Farming development and irrigation

Farmers migrating to Colorado found a large percentage of sunny days and low humidity, both very favorable for crop production given adequate moisture. But with annual precipitation of just 12 to 15 inches in the plains east of the mountains, irrigation was employed where water was available (Census 1920). Consequently, farming development spread out mostly adjacent to the three major watercourses located in the north (Platte River), the south (Rio Grande River), and the southeast (Arkansas River). Farming by irrigation produced much more output per acre compared with farming in the more humid areas of the country. But irrigated farming also entailed much higher capital expenditures and required more attention by the farmer to matters related to securing and protecting rights to water (Taylor 1907).

Early irrigation in Colorado produced vegetables for the miners; these ditches were small, narrow structures that irrigated just a few acres. Lands nearest the streams were cultivated first; as these lands became fully claimed, additional irrigation development required larger and more elaborate irrigation works that could carry water to lands farther from the streambed (Dunbar 1983). The diversion of water for use on lands not adjacent to the watercourse arose from the necessities presented by the dry and arid environment.

Following the Civil War, westward expansion of the railroad network transformed local agriculture from small-scale production for local markets to large-scale, more specialized, enterprises producing largely for markets in the East and overseas. By providing connections to large market centers in Chicago and New York, rail expansion created strong incentives for farmers to produce more than could be consumed by local markets. Access to New York for farmers in the West also provided access to large European markets via transatlantic shipments.

Falling rail and shipping costs quickened the pace of market integration. From the 1880s to 1910, for example, the cost of shipping a bushel of wheat from Chicago to New York fell from 8.6 cents to 5.4 cents, and the cost of transatlantic shipment dropped by nearly two-thirds. Declining transportation costs caused grain prices in Chicago, New York, and Liverpool to move much closer together. By World War I, the price of wheat was nearly the same at all three locations. Market integration greatly increased access to large markets for Colorado farmers, but also made them more dependent on economic and weather conditions far from home (Atack, Bateman, and Parker 2000).

Strong demand, favorable local climate, and good soil enhanced by irrigation created ideal conditions for crop production and livestock. Nearly seven in ten dollars from irrigated cultivation in Colorado during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries can be attributed to five crops: alfalfa, potatoes, sugar beets, fruit (mostly apples), and wheat. By 1909, Colorado produced threefifths of the entire western irrigated crop of sugar beets and thirty-five percent of the irrigated potatoes (Census 1910). The production of irrigated alfalfa was important as a source of livestock feed during the long and bitter winter seasons when forage is scarce.

The need to spread fixed costs over more acres of production combined with increasing market demand for crops and livestock created strong incentives for the development of larger farms. Consequently, farmers took on more debt to purchase additional land and new or expanded irrigation works (Boyd 1897).

Early irrigation works in the 1860s were often simple, consisting of a crude stream diversion and a short ditch. Soon, however, farmers discovered that they must combine to build and maintain expensive irrigation works; these organized efforts were termed 'irrigation enterprises' by the Census Bureau. Between 1860 and 1880, nearly 1,600 new irrigation enterprises came into existence. The number of irrigation enterprises more than doubled in the 1880s so that by 1890, 58.9 percent of all farms and 19.4 percent all land in farms were irrigated. By 1900, 71.3 percent of all farms in the state were irrigated (Census 1910).

Capital expenditures for new irrigation enterprises in Colorado averaged $11 per acre in the 1870s and 1880s, climbing to $19 per acre in the 1890s, $49 per acre between 1900 and 1910 and $82 per acre from 1910 to 1914, all in 1900 dollars. Once the easily reclaimed lands were developed, providing irrigation to additional lands required moving water a greater distance from the watercourse to higher elevations, requiring much greater capital expenditure per acre. In addition, capital spending in the 1890s and later had much to do with building storage reservoirs, improving existing ditches, and building new ditches within existing irrigation enterprises.

After 1900 the number of irrigated farms continued to rise, but more slowly than the number of farms with no irrigation, reducing the proportion of farms under irrigation to 56 percent in 1910 and 48 percent in 1920. The rapid growth of dryland farming was partly a consequence of the escalating cost of irrigation and partly due to the development of techniques for moisture-saving cultivation, drought-resistant varieties of crops, and the introduction of the gasoline tractor in the early twentieth century; these influences combined to greatly improve the ability of farmers to grow crops without expensive irrigation (Hundley 1988).

Farmers enjoyed favorably wet weather in the early 1880s; from that time until World War I, the weather alternated, with one or two wet years followed with one or two dry years. Below average precipitation and low stream flow caused crop output to fall from the previous year in 1890, 1893, 1896, 1899, 1902, and so on. Due to the depression beginning in 1890, world markets for grain were in surplus due to high production in Canada, South America, and Australia. Falling grain prices in conjunction with very dry weather caused widespread economic hardship; real crop prices had dropped 21 percent in Colorado.

A lesson learned from the dry years was that more irrigation is needed to smooth out the persistent spells of low precipitation and more reservoirs are needed to smooth out high and low periods of stream flow. Consequently, the number of storage dams doubled in the 1880s and continued to be built at a robust pace until 1915. Between 1889 and 1899 the number of acres under irrigation increased 81 percent, mostly in wheat and other cereals and alfalfa hay and Colorado surpassed California in the number of irrigated acres and was second largest to California in the value of irrigated crops (Census 1910 and 1920).

Between 1910 and 1920, production on irrigated lands rose partly due to increased demand domestically and partly because of higher demand from Europe to feed the hungry population of warring nations. Corn, wheat, alfalfa, and sugar beets all experienced significantly greater output, although the greatest impact on farmers was the much higher prices for crops during this period.

2. Development of legal precedents

Three overlapping but distinct periods of water rights litigation can be identified. In the earliest period, from about 1872 to the early 1890s, the majority of court cases dealt with upholding and refining the doctrine of prior appropriation. During this period the riparian water rights system in place was set aside in favor of doctrine prior appropriation, a system more suited to the dry climate. In the second period, from about 1892 through about 1904, cases involving irrigation enterprises were prominent. These cases dealt with defining the rights of irrigation cooperatives and partnerships relative to the irrigators and other irrigation enterprises. Finally, cases regarding storage reservoirs, water rights transfers, and changes in the point of diversion were prominent in the third period beginning in about 1905.

Figure 1 shows a spurt of litigation from 1890 to 1892, mostly involving irrigation enterprises, with the volume of court cases dropping until 1905 when a second surge of litigation occurs. One might expect in the absence of well-defined rules during the earliest period of settlement, the courts provided the most attractive means of dispute resolution (Khan 2000). As the rules of water usage became more clearly established over time, the number of disputed issues will decline.

Legal precedents established in a body of case law provide courts an important method of using an earlier decision to decide a similar case in the same way (Landes and Posner 1976). Precedents can be viewed as a stock of legal knowledge that, over time, improves the predictability of the law (Miceli 2004). An example can be found in a recent study of litigation on the Australian frontier. Khan (2000) shows an initial surge in litigation was followed with a long-term declining trend in the late 1800s. She argues that the as the stock of legal capital grows, standards became more routine and predictable, reducing the probability of future litigation on similar issues.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The earliest important case was decided by the Colorado Supreme Court in 1872. In Yunker v. Nichols, (1) the court first recognized an absolute need for diverting water from the watercourse. Reversing the decision of the lower court, the court held that the dry Colorado climate, the right to divert water from the watercourse and the right to convey water through land owned by others are necessities. In the opinion of Chief Justice Hallett,
   In a dry and thirsty land it is necessary to
   divert the water of streams from their natural
   channels, in order to obtain the fruits of the
   soil. The value and usefulness of agricultural
   lands, in this territory, depend on the supply
   of water for irrigation, and this can only be
   obtained by constructing artificial channels
   through which it may flow over adjacent
   lands (p. 552).


Priority of water rights was specifically recognized later in the Colorado constitution in 1876, following the customs and rules laid down by the miners nearly two decades earlier. In 1878 the Colorado Supreme Court again re-affirmed priority of rights to water in Schilling v. Rominger. (2)

Legal challenges from riparian water users continued to arise, however. In 1882 the Colorado Supreme Court issued a very clear statement of the right of diversion and right of priority. In Coffin v. Left Hand Ditch, (3) the court found that without the rights to divert and transport water, hallmarks of the system of prior appropriation, farmers would have little incentive to grow crops:
   ... vast expenditures of time and money
   have been made in reclaiming and fertilizing
   by irrigation portions of our unproductive
   territory. Houses have been built, and permanent
   improvements made; the soil has been
   cultivated, and thousands of acres have been
   rendered immensely valuable, with the understanding
   that appropriations of water
   would be protected. Deny the doctrine of priority
   of appropriation, and a great part of the
   value of all this property is at once destroyed
   (pp. 448-449).


The court ruled that the common law doctrine of riparian rights is inapplicable in Colorado due to the arid climate and the necessity of diverting water from the watercourse. The court also held that the first person to appropriate, or divert, the water and put to a beneficial use has the prior right.

Although the Coffin decision definitively repudiated riparian rights, legal challenges to the doctrine of prior appropriation still occurred but with less frequency. From 1882 to 1909 the court ruled against riparian rights in five separate cases. In the last case, Sternberger v. Seaton, (4) an exasperated court argued that to recognize a riparian right "... would require the reversal of decisions of the court, tearing up the statute laws, and nullification of provisions of the constitution." Eventually the rights of diversion and prior appropriation were accepted as the undisputed law, but only after a period of challenge after challenge by those who felt threatened.

The next period of litigation involved irrigation enterprises and corporate canal companies. As lands nearest the rivers and streams were settled, the development of additional cropland required transporting water to lands much farther from the watercourse. Much more capital investment was needed to build these new, more expensive irrigation works, creating strong incentives for the development of irrigation enterprises that could develop and maintain diversion works and ditches. The most prevalent form of these enterprises consisted of cooperative ventures, partnerships between farmers, and corporate-owned enterprises.

As can be imagined, the ambiguities of the rights of irrigation enterprises vis-a-vis the rights of irrigators generated a great deal of litigation* During the 1890s, the Supreme Court and appellate courts in Colorado decided 21 cases dealing with irrigation enterprises, compared with just three cases in the previous decade. In the Wheeler (5) case, for example, the Colorado Supreme Court ruled that the rights to water belong to the irrigator, and the irrigation enterprise could legally impose fees related to canal upkeep and transportation costs, but could not charge a perpetual fee for the use of the water* The number of court cases that dealt with the irrigation enterprises peaked during the 1890s and held steady in the 1900s and 1910s.

Most of the legal issues relating to prior appropriations and irrigation enterprises had been settled by the early 1900s. Farming growth, however, continued unabated, causing incentives for irrigators to search for new ways to increase the amount of water available for growing crops. As the density of diversion facilities increased over time, irrigators found that they could more efficiently use their water by changing the point of diversion from one place to another. Other irrigators found profit in selling water rights to rapidly growing municipalities, thus raising legal issues regarding the transferability of water rights.

In addition, irrigating enterprises built expensive reservoirs that allowed storage of waters during the spring when stream flow typically is swollen by melting snow cover in the mountains* Stored water could be used to irrigate crops in the late summer when stream flow is much smaller* The first storage reservoirs began to appear in the mid-1880s in the Cache la Poudre Valley (Dunbar 1983).

The water-supply enhancing innovations of water storage, water rights transfers, and changes in the point of diversion raised a new set of issues for the courts to sort out. The volume of litigation on these issues increased from just four cases in the 1890s to sixteen cases 1900-1909 and seventeen cases 1910-1919.

The total volume of water rights litigation peaked in about 1906, then gradually declined. Several factors may have contributed to the decline in water rights defining and enforcing activity. First, as mentioned earlier, the emergence of case law precedents reduced the need for the courts to address the same issues over and over. Second, dryland farming increased greatly during the 1900s in response to the rapidly escalating capital costs of irrigation. Dryland farms add to crop production without increasing the demand for water. Third, increasing storage of water during the wet season for use during the growing season helped mitigate periods of water shortage. Court cases recognizing the right to build reservoirs on the stream bed and financing generated by the federal Reclamation Act, created incentives for new reservoirs that reduced the effects of droughts on the availability of water for irrigation (Fox 1918). As noted by Tarlock (2001), dams reduced the need to enforce water rights in the courts, thus lowering the number of lawsuits undertaken.

The history of Colorado water rights development demonstrates how the water rights defining and enforcing activity changed over time as economic circumstances changed. Early irrigators defended the rule of diversion and priority of right in order to protect their investments in the farm enterprise. Increased demand for food fostered large capital investments in ditches and canals, resulting in the emergence of irrigation enterprises and canal corporations, raising new issues for property rights defining and enforcing activity. Increases in water storage, dryland farming, and changes in the point of diversion characterize the final period of water rights litigation.

III. Theoretical Background

Anderson (1982) offers testable propositions regarding property rights defining and enforcing activity. First, higher market values or greater scarcity will cause individuals to strengthen their claims to resources. Second, an increase in the probability of losing an asset will increase property rights enforcing activity. In this section, we outline how these propositions can be examined empirically in the context of Colorado water rights litigation.

In the present model, water rights defining and enforcing activity depends on the value of water: the higher its value, the greater the benefits from additional defining and enforcing activity. The value of water depends at a minimum on five factors, (a) prices of irrigated farm crops, (b) production costs, (c) farm production per acre or productivity, (d) the number of acres under irrigation and (e) the quantity of water available in the stream.

Following Anderson (1982) the value of water will rise if the output price of irrigated crops goes up. This assumes that the price elasticity of supply is non-negligible. Conversely, a rise in production cost can be expected to reduce production and, hence, the value of water. The value of water is anticipated to increase as farm productivity goes up, as measured by higher output per acre. The demand for water and, hence, its value will rise if more land is irrigated. As more water is available in rivers, the value of water and, hence, water rights enforcement activity should decrease.

An important implication of this model inspired by Anderson (1982) is that irrigators will increase their efforts to protect and define their rights to water when their demand for water increases or when the supply of water decreases.

IV. Data

The number of court cases (cases) dealing with water rights is chosen as a measure of water rights defining and enforcing activity (Figure 1). This is the variable to be explained by the model. Court cases dealing with water rights at the Supreme Court and appellate levels are collected from several editions of the American Digest, a publication that lists headnotes of court cases by legal category. Cases are selected from the category "Water and Water Courses" from four editions of the Digest. Case headnotes are scanned to ensure that the case is related, in general, to the protection or definition of the right to water. Some cases and categories of cases are excluded. Cases involving damages to land due to water seepage from canals, for example, do not involve the value of water and so are excluded. Subcategories such as "Bed and Banks" are also excluded. The types of cases included range from issues such as rights of way to damages due to loss of flow, and from appurtenance to the validity of the system of prior rights. (6)

The regressors to explain the number of water rights court cases per year are identified in Table 1. The list of variables includes more variables than are used for the preferred models presented in the results section.

The demand for water and its value is directly tied to the level of irrigated farming. Two alternative variables are employed to account for this relationship: the number of irrigated farms (ifarms) in Colorado and the acreage under cultivation by irrigated farms (acresifarms). The variable ifarms is estimated using decennial census figures. (7) Annual figures for ifarms and acresifarms are assumed to grow at the same rate within a given decade, determined by the annualized census-to-census growth rate.

The output price of irrigated crops is represented by the real production-weighted output price of five key crops (pout) in the early history of Colorado. An estimated consumer price index from the Historical Statistics of the United States is used to deflate crop values per bushel. As seen in Figure 2, real prices declined from the 1880s to the 1890s, probably due to the depression and deflationary pressures during the mid 1890s. During the period 1904-11, however, output prices soared, probably reflecting rising world demand for crops. Crop values in Colorado increased 27 percent from their level of 1882-89. Real output prices jumped again during World War I, although to a much larger degree than before. By far, the largest proportion of the crops represented by the output price index was grown on irrigated farms. In value terms, according to the 1890 census, irrigated crops accounted for 89 percent of all crops grown in Colorado. (8)

The variable output per acre (outacre) represents farm productivity. It is calculated from data for five key crops. (9) As discussed above, most of the crops grown during this period were irrigated. In 1909, for example, 96 percent of the alfalfa production was irrigated as was 65 percent of the wheat produced, 71 percent of the potato production, and 99 percent of the sugar beet production (Census 1920).

Stream flow data (flow) are taken from U.S. Geological Survey (1954, 1958) publications. Criteria for selection of rivers and recording stations include the completeness of early records and the location of the river. Based on these criteria, two rivers are selected: the Cache la Poudre, recorded at Ft. Collins, and the Arkansas River, recorded at Canyon City. Much of the farmland irrigated in Colorado depends on the flow of these two rivers. An index of stream flow is used since it reflects variations of flow around a base level without regard to the nominal quantities. The flow index is constructed from the mean of the nominal flows of the Cache la Poudre and Arkansas Rivers, with the base set at the mean level of the combined flows.

Farmers must be concerned not only with the value of crops or revenue but also with the cost of production. Unfortunately, direct cost data do not exist for Colorado farms. However, some variables can be identified that are likely to capture key cost components. The railway freight cost of moving wheat from Chicago to New York is such a cost component. If it can be taken as a proxy for transportation costs in general, it would be relevant for farmers as an input cost. To the extent that farmers rely on credit for their operations, the commercial paper rate could be considered a measure of short-term credit cost.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

V. Estimation Results

The time series properties of the data do not allow for cointegation methods. In particular, as is evident from Figure 1, the dependent variable does not follow an obvious trend. As a result, ordinary least squares is employed to identify the determinants of water rights litigation. The estimation results are summarized in Table 2. Particular emphasis is placed on checking that the empirical models capture the data generating process. (10) To document model fit, probability values for a number of statistical specification tests are provided. No statistical problems are evident for any of the models at the five percent level. Simultaneous equations problems are excluded because all regressor variables enter with a lag of at least one year. In fact, most variables have a significantly longer lag structure associated with it. Two models are estimated in levels and two in log-linear format. There are few differences in the statistical adequacy tests to prefer one specification over the other. The main reason for including both specifications is to allow for alternative economic interpretations of the estimated coefficients. The estimates in levels (Models 1 and 2) provide for marginal effects, the log-linear estimates (Models 3 and 4) for elasticities. (11)

As predicted by the theoretical considerations of Anderson (1982), stream flow as measured by variable flow has a negative impact on the incidence of water rights litigation, while output per acre (outacre) and the acreage planted by irrigated farms (acresifarms) have positive coefficients (Models 1 and 3). As an alternative to the variable acresifarms the number of irrigated farms (ifarms) is used in Models 2 and 4. Both variables are statistically highly significant. The elasticity of ifarms is close to unity, that of acresifarms is somewhat less. Water rights litigation is also proportional, with an elasticity of one, to farm productivity (outacre). These results are consistent with the predictions provided in the theoretical background. This also applies to the negative unitary elasticity of water rights cases with respect to stream flow (flow).

By contrast, the estimation results collected in Table 2 do not confirm the idea that a rise in output price (pout) or a reduction in production cost, as proxied by freight cost (freight), lead to more water rights litigation. In fact, the estimated coefficients point in exactly the opposite direction and at least for variable pout the estimated effect is highly significant statistically. To check on the sensitivity of the results to the large increase in pout during the war years (Figure 2), we re-estimate the equations of Table 2 for a sample that ends in 1914 instead of in 1920. Compared to Table 2, the coefficients of variables pout and freight increase in absolute value. This suggests that the inclusion of the war years for the regressions reported in Table 2 are not responsible for the negative and significant impact of pout or the positive and significant impact of freight on the number of court cases.

We propose the following explanation of this inconsistency with the theory related to water rights. Falling output prices and rising production costs do indeed lower the implied value of water, but they also threaten the very survival of farmers. The latter threat is likely to dominate farmers' actions. However, how farmers react to strong price and cost pressures is widely discussed in the literature on rent seeking and the demand for agricultural protection mentioned earlier. In particular, lower output prices or higher production costs tend to raise the demand for internal or external protection by farmers. Litigating water rights can be interpreted in this context as just another way of farmers to seek internal protection. (12) In this case, protection is sought in the courts, not from legislators. Seeking protection in the courts is the preferred mode in the late 1800s and early 1900s not only because the problems are localized, but also because farming is still too large a sector to make government protection feasible (Zietz and Valdes, 1993). Later in time, as agriculture shrinks in relative size, farmers' demand for protection is directly addressed to legislators. In the case of the U.S., it has resulted in an extensive system of government price supports and input subsidies (Gardner 1987). In fact, this trend to protect U.S. agriculture from the free forces of the market started after the output price spike triggered by World War I (Figure 2).

VI. Summary and Conclusions

The paper examines the development of water rights in Colorado during the latter part of the 18th and early part of the 19th century. The model is based on theoretical work on the evolution of property rights for natural resources and in particular water. According to the theoretical model, greater water rights defining and enforcing activity is expected whenever (a) the demand for water increases or (b) the supply of water decreases.

The empirical model explains the annual number of water rights court cases in Colorado for the years 1884 to 1920. Among the determinants of water rights cases are the number of irrigated farms, farm productivity, farm output price, and level of stream flow. The empirical model confirms that proxies for the demand and supply of water can explain a good part of the level of water rights litigation over time: litigation increases when the potential benefits of additional property rights defining and enforcing activity rise. This result confirms a basic hypothesis in the economics literature on property rights. However, it is also apparent from the estimation results that property rights alone cannot account for all the empirical regularities. The fact that litigation activity rises with a decrease in farm output price and with an increase in cost requires some alternative explanation. It is suggested that this behavior is consistent with the predictions of the literature on agricultural protection: farmers seek protection against the specter of default by litigating in the courts. After Word War I, they redirect their demand for protection from the courts to the government.

Enforcing and protecting property rights to water is clearly no less of an issue today than it was in 19th century Colorado. In fact, there is significant potential for serious future conflict not only in the arid parts of the Western U.S. but also in many parts of the world outside the U.S., including the Middle East. Many of the property rights issues for water outside the U.S. are likely to require international litigation and the development of a set of new international rules and regulations.

References

American Digest 1658 to 1896, Vendor and Purchaser to Willful Injuries, (St. Paul, MN: West Publishing, 1904).

American Digest 1897 to 1906, Vendor and Purchaser to Zinc, (St. Paul, MN: West Publishing, 1910).

American Digest 1907 to 1916, War to Zoological Societies, (St. Paul, MN: West Publishing, 1922). American Digest 1916 to 1926, Trover and Conversion to Wharves, (St. Paul, MN: West Publishing, 1929).

Anderson, T.L., "Institutional Underpinnings of the Water Crisis," Cato Journal, Vol. 2, 1982, 759-792.

Anderson, T.L., Water Crisis: Ending the Policy Drought, (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1983).

Anderson, K. and Y. Hayami, The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International Perspective. (Sydney: Allen and Unwin, 1987).

Atack, J., F. Bateman, and W.N. Parker, "The Farm, the Farmer, and the Market," Chapter 6 in The Cambridge Economic History of the United States, Volume 1, Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman, editors, (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000), 245-284.

Belsley, D.A., E. Kuh, and R.E. Welsch, "Identifying Influential Data and Sources of Collinearity", Regression Diagnostics, (New York: Wiley, 1980).

Boyd, D., "Irrigation Near Greeley Colorado," U.S. Geological Survey, (Washington, D.C: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1897).

Demsetz, H., "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 57, 1967, 347-359.

Doornik, J.A. and H. Hansen, "An Omnibus Test for Univariate and Multivariate Normality," Working paper W4&91, December, (Oxford, U.K: Nuffield College, 1994).

Dunbar, R., Forging New Rights in Western Waters, (Lincoln and London: University of Nebraska Press, 1983).

Durbin, J., and S.J. Koopman, Time Series Analysis by State Space Methods, (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, 2001).

Eschelbach Gregson, M., "Rural Response to Increased Demand: Crop Choice in the Midwest 1860-1880," Journal of Economic History, Vol. 53, 1993, 332-345.

Fox, L.P., "State Regulation of the Canal Corporation in Colorado," Michigan Law Review, 1918, Vol. 16.

Fox, L.P., "Origins and Early Development of Populism in Colorado," Ph.D. dissertation, University of Pennsylvania, 1916.

Gardner, B.L., "Causes of U.S. Farm Commodity Programs," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 95, 1987, 290-310.

Honma, M., and Y. Hayami, "The Structure of Agricultural Protection in Industrial Countries," Journal of International Economics, Vol. 20, 1986, 115-129.

Hundley, Jr., N., "The Great American Desert Transformed: Aridity, Exploitation, and Imperialism in the Making of the Modern American West," in Water and Arid Lands of the Western United States, Chapter 2, Mohamed T. El-Ashry and Diana C. Gibbons, editors, (New York: World Resources Institute: 1988), 21-84.

Khan, B.Z., "Commerce and Cooperation: Litigation and Settlement of Civil Disputes on the Australian Frontier, 1860-1900", Journal of Economic History, Vol. 60, 2000, 1088-1119.

Krueger, A., "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society," American Economic Review, Vol. 64, 1974, 291-303.

Landes, W.M. and R.A. Posner., "Legal Precedent: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis," Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 19, 1976, 249-307.

Ljung, G.M., G.E.P. Box, "On a Measure of Lack of Fit in Time Series Models," Biometrika, Vol. 65, 1978, 297-303.

Miceli, T.J., The Economic Approach to Law, (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2004).

Newell, F.H., "1890: Report on Agriculture by Irrigation in the Western United States," in Eleventh Census of the United States, U.S. Department of the Interior, Census Office, 1894.

Pejovich, S., The Economics of Property Rights: Toward a Theory of Comparative Systems, (Boston, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1990), Online version.

Schwarz, G., "Estimating the Dimension of a Model," Annals of Statistics, Vol. 6, 1978, 461-464.

Tarlock, A.D., "The Future of Prior Appropriation in the New West," Natural Resources Journal, Vol. 41, 2001, 769-793.

Taylor, H.C., "Economic Problems in Agriculture by Irrigation," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 15, 1907, 209-228.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Statistics, "Corn Crops of the United States, 1866-1906," Bulletin No. 56. (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1907a).

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Statistics, "Wheat Crops of the United States, 1866-1906," Bulletin No. 57. (Washington, D.C: Government Printing Office, 1907b).

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Statistics, "Hay Crops of the United States, 1866-1906," Bulletin No. 63. (Washington, D.C: Government Printing Office, 1908a).

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Statistics, "Potato Crops of the United States, 1866-1906," Bulletin No. 58. (Washington, D.C: Government Printing Office, 1908b).

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Division of Publications, Yearbook of the United States Department of Agriculture, (Washington, D.C: Government Printing Office, 1907-1920).

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, "Agriculture, 1909 and 1910," Thirteenth Census of the United States, Volume V, (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1913).

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970, Part 1. (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1976).

U.S. Geological Survey, Compilation of Records of Surface Waters of the United States through September 1950, Part 9: Colorado River Basin, Water Supply Paper No. 1313. (Washington, D.C: Government Printing Office, 1954).

U.S. Geological Survey, Compilation of Records of Surface Waters of the United States through September 1950, Parts 6-8: Missouri River Basin below Sioux City, Iowa, Water Supply Paper No. 1310. (Washington, D.C: Government Printing Office, 1958).

Williams, W.D., "Irrigation Law in Colorado, Part II," Rocky Mountain Law Review, Vol. 10, 1938, 87-104.

Zietz, J. and A. Valdes, "The Growth of Agricultural Protection," Chapter 5 in Trade and Protectionism, NBER-East Asia Seminar on Economics, Vol. 2, T. Ito and A. O. Krueger, editors, (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1993) 115-143.

Notes

(1.) 1 Colo. 551 (1872).

(2.) 4 Colo. 100 (1878).

(3.) 6 Colo. 443 (1882).

(4.) 45 Colo. 401 (1909).

(5.) Wheeler v. Northern Colorado Irrigation Co., 10 Colo. 582 (1886), discussed more fully in Williams (1938).

(6.) See American Digest 1658 to 1896 (1904), American Digest 1897 to 1906 (1910), American Digest 1907 to 1916 (1922), American Digest 1916 to 1926 (1929).

(7.) Census figures on the number of farms are obtained from the "Historical Statistics of the United States," Colonial Times to 1970, Part 1, 1976.

(8.) U.S. Department of the Interior, Census Office (1894), p. 90. Wheat cultivation dominated early irrigation in Colorado until the early 1880s. Falling relative wheat prices encouraged diversification into corn, oats, and alfalfa. But alfalfa required three to four times more water per acre than did wheat, thereby exacerbating water shortages in the late 18808 (Fox 1916, pp. 133-34).

(9.) The data are collected from U.S. Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Statistics (1907a, 1907b, 1908a, 1908b) and the Yearbook of Agriculture, volumes 1907 to 1920.

(10.) All models are estimated in Stamp 6.0, which is a structural time series package discussed in Durbin and Koopman (2001). The program allows for the inclusion of unobserved trend components. This can be of importance for model fit and interpretation if critical regressor variables that drive the dependent variable over time are unobserved. The empirical results, however, do not suggest that unobserved components play a significant role in the current case. Hence, ordinary least squares emerges as the appropriate technique.

(11.) The variable ishort is not included in the preferred models because it is not significant at typical levels of statistical confidence or its coefficient is not sufficiently robust to slight modifications of the model.

(12.) Compare on this also the interpretation of Eschelbach Gregson (1993): "German rural economists ... were among the first to recognize that as transport costs fell, inherent soil suitability became more important ... As the constraints imposed by high transportation costs are ameliorated, the constraints imposed by nature become binding." (p. 334).

David A. Penn, Director, Business and Economic Research Center Middle Tennessee State University, Box 102 Murfreesboro, TN 37132, E-mail: [email protected] Phone: (615) 904-8571

Joachim Zietz, Department of Economics and Finance Middle Tennessee State University, Box 129 Murfreesboro, TN 37132, E-mail: [email protected] Phone: (615) 898-5619
TABLE 1.
Definition of Variables and Basic Statistics, 1884-1920

Variable      Definition                   Mean     Minimum   Maximum

cases         number of Colorado water       9.38         1        19
              rights cases heard by the
              supreme and appellate
              courts

acresifarms   acres on irrigated farms    1879.92    342.70   3348.40
              in Colorado, 1,000s

ifarms        number of irrigated farms     18.30      4.40     28.80
              in Colorado, 1,000s

pout          production weighted real     117.34     73.70    265.70
              price index of corn,
              wheat, potatoes, hay, and
              oats (adjusted by the
              consumer price index),
              Colorado, 1900 = 100

outacre       output of corn, wheat,         1.83      1.20      2.52
              potatoes, hay, and oats,
              in 1900 prices, per acre,
              Colorado

flow          annual combined index of     104.41        49       218
              stream flow for two
              rivers in Colorado

freight       average freight rate of       11.93      8.80     16.47
              wheat, Chicago to New
              York, cents per bushel

ishort        U.S. Commercial Paper          4.81      3.04      7.37
              Rate, New York City,
              series m 13002 in NBER,
              Macrohistory Database

TABLE 2.
Estimation Results, Ordinary Least Squares, 1889-1920

                                    Levels              Logs

Variables                   Model 1    Model 2   Model 3   Model 4

constant                     -2.581    -8.495     1.578     4.662
                            (-0.766)   (0.397)   (0.673)   (0.131)
acresifarms_3                 0.004               0.867
                             -0.03               (0.005)
ifarms_4                                0.554               1.013
                                       (0.019)             (0.008)
pout_1                       -0.067    -0.068    -1.135    -1.065
                             -0.001    (0.001)   (0.000)   (0.000)
outacre_4                     5.835     5.357     1.089     1.087
                             -0.009    (0.017)   (0.021)   (0.024)
flow_4                       -0.097    -0.095    -0.993    -0.988
                              0        (0.000)   (0.000)   (0.000)
freight_2                     1.102     1.417     1.423     1.479
                             -0.055    (0.031)   (0.081)   (0.090)
[R.sup.2]                     0.6117    0.6232    0.6889    0.6790
BIC                           2.597     2.567    -1.763    -1.732
condition number             26        25        56        63
Durbin-Watson                 1.8459    1.8990    1.8137    1.7704
p-values:
  Ljung-Box Q (6 lags)        0.7906    0.8628    0.9918    0.9931
  Heteroskedasticity          0.4212    0.4119    0.7963    0.8086
  Normality-DH                0.4093    0.6569    0.2296    0.1969
  Chow (50 percent)           0.3098    0.3390    0.6462    0.6893
  Chow (90 percent)           0.0921    0.0737    0.0585    0.0598
  Failure [chi square](5)     0.0828    0.0554    0.0544    0.0603
  Cusum t(5)                  0.2605    0.2227    0.0806    0.0827

Notes: cases and its natural logarithm are the dependent variables
for the level and log equations, respectively; lags  are identified
by an underscore following the variable name; p-values are liven in
parenthesis. [R.sup.2] and the Schwarz's  (1978) Bayesian
Information Criterion (BIC) are not directly comparable across the
level and log equations.  Collinearity is checked with the condition
number suggested by Belsley et al. (1980). Ljung-Box Q is the Ljung
and Box (1978) test for autocorrelation up to lag order 6. Normality
is checked with the Doornik and Hansen (1994)  test. Structural
stability is checked with two Chow tests and with two 5-period
one-step-ahead out-of-sample  forecasting tests (Failure and Cusum,
respectively). All adequacy tests are passed at the five percent
level or better.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有