Application of logistic models for stock market bubbles analysis.
Girdzijauskas, Stasys ; Streimikiene, Dalia
1. Introduction
A stock market bubble in the financial markets is the term that is
applied to a self-propagating rise or increase in the share prices of
stocks in a particular industry or sector. The term "stock market
bubble" can only be used with any certainty in retrospect when
share prices have since fallen drastically or crashed. A bubble happens
when speculators notice the swift rise in value of stocks and then
decide to buy more of the same stocks as a way of anticipating further
rises rather than because the shares have been undervalued. This buying
spree results in many companies' shares becoming grossly overvalued creating a widening discrepancy between the share price and the actual
value of the stocks. When the bubble bursts the share prices will fall
very swiftly and dramatically, with the falling prices trying to seek
the fundamental value of the stocks. This can actually result in many
companies going out of business.
There are several recent investigations of economic growth and
implications of sustainable development concept on economic growth
performed in Lithuania (Grundey 2008; Zavadskas 2008). In most cases,
the growth of economy, or growth of the capital is not subject to any
restrictions, however EU environmental policies, etc. put some
restrictions on economic growth (Streimikiene, Esekina 2008) because of
limited capacity of environment to absorb pollution. In general, from
the theoretical perspective, capital is considered to be of unlimited
growth. Nevertheless, such an estimation of capital is not accurate. In
the paper, the analyzed capital is related to the finite resources of
growth; in other words, it cannot develop endlessly. Thus, the paper
focuses on the functions of limited growth, or on logistic functions
that describe the process of capital accumulation (i.e. growth).
The specificity of the logistic function lies in its limited growth
aspect. To say more, it undergoes alteration exclusively within a
described interval: from zero to a particular (maximum) rate. The
logistic growth is a characteristic feature not only with respect to
capital but, actually, to any population whose rate of growth is
proportional to their size. In the following analysis of the capital
growth functions, the financial resources will be considered. The
resources of capital growth are related to some particular environment
in which they are invested. Here the resources of capital development
are understood as the greatest capital amount which may be invested in
such an environment.
On the whole, the logistic models are widely applied for the
investigation of the biological systems. In the field of economic
enquiry, they have been seldom applied--only single attempts at the
analysis of the economic systems have been discovered by the authors
(Ferreira 1998; Shone 2001; Sterman 2000). The main drawback of such
models is that they do not offer the growth function expressed in
compound interest. In Lithuania, the exploration of the mentioned
problem started in 2002 (Girdzijauskas 2002; Merkevicius et al. 2006;
Girdzijauskas et al. 2007; Girdzijauskas 2008).
The article aims to analyse the origin of stock market bubbles
creation based on logistic capital growth model.
2. Stock market bubbles
Two major stock market bubbles happened in the late 1990s and early
in 2000 in the USA. The soaring market of the 1990s was seen by many
economists as the harbinger of a new age sustained, rapid economic
growth. The same situation was in 1920. As in the 1990s it was widely
claimed that a new economy had taken root in the USA. In both periods,
unemployment was low with stable prices in the twenties and low
inflation in the nineties. Participation in the market increased, as
investing in the market seemed safer, with reduced macroeconomic risk
and the seeming abundance of high return opportunities (White 2006).
In both 1920 and 1990 the boom was explained by scientists as
driven by technological change raising dividends. The idea of
technological age played a key role in the mind of the 1990s' bull
market. The rapid changes in computer/information technology and
biotechnology were heralded as placing the economy on a higher
trajectory. The new era vision was supported by many economists. It was
expected that technology would have an even greater impact on
productivity growth. Like in the 1920s the conclusion for 1990 was
fairly clear--the expected dividend growth was not a major factor
driving the boom (Eatwell 2004).
Several articles were published analysing and comparing the
situations in 1920 and 1990 and trying to provide the explanations of
stock market bubbles (White 2006; Eatwell 2004; Pastor, Veronesi 2004;
Cochrane 2002; Caballero, Hammour 2002; Kraay, Ventura 2005; DeLong,
Magin 2001).
Different economists provide different explanations. Pastor and
Veronesi (2004) studied the NASDAQ bubble and argued that the
fundamental value of a firm increases with uncertainty about average
future profitability, and this uncertainty was unusually high in the
late 1990s. Authors stated, that the models which had been used to value
technology stocks omitted an important determinant of the fundamental
value, namely the uncertainty about a firm's average future
profitability, which can also be thought of as the uncertainty about the
average future growth rate of the firm's books value. According to Pastor and Veronesi (2004) the late 1990s witnessed high uncertainty
about the average growth rates of technology firms, and that this
uncertainty was partly responsible for the high level of technology
stock prices. Cochrane (2002) suggested that a mechanism much like the
transactions demand for money drove many stock prices above the
"fundamental value".
Caballero and Hammour (2002) interpreted a stock market bubble as a
high-valuation equilibrium with the low effective cost of capital based
on optimism about the future availability of funds for investment.
Authors showed in their investigation that such bubbles arise naturally
when the expansion is concentrated in the "new economy" sector
and when it is supported by sustained financial surpluses, both of which
would constitute an integral part, as cause and consequence, of a
"speculative growth" equilibrium. The high-valuation
equilibrium may take the form of a stock market bubble. In contrast to
classic bubbles on non-productive assets, the bubbles in the Caballero
and Hammour (2002) model encourage real investments, boost long run
savings, and may appear in dynamically efficient economies. In the
particular case of the U.S. in the 1990s, the authors argue that at
least two factors created the conditions for a speculative growth
episode: the emerging information technology sector and conservative
fiscal policy. Both factors created favourable conditions for
growth-saving feedback and for the possibility of a speculative
equilibrium characterized by extreme stock market valuations and a
potential crash. Kraay and Ventura (2005) have provided a joint account
of some of the major US macroeconomic events of the past decade: large
current account deficits and a steady decline in the net foreign asset
position; the large boom and a subsequent crash in the stock market; and
the emergence of large fiscal deficits. According to the conventional
view, the evolution of the stock market and fiscal deficits are more or
less unrelated events, with the former driven by sharp swings in US
productivity, and the latter by shifting US political considerations.
Both of these, in turn, fuelled current account deficits that must
eventually be reversed as the accumulation of public debt becomes
excessive.
Kraay and Ventura (2005) proposed two alternative views in which
the stock market and the fiscal deficits are closely linked. Authors
stated that the US economy contains "pockets" of inefficiency.
This opens the possibility for asset bubbles to exist, which in turn
provides a more plausible explanation for the large swings in equity
values over the past decade. The appearance of a bubble in the US stock
market in the second half of the 1990s accounts for much of the decline
in US net foreign assets during this period. At the same time, the
bubble raised welfare worldwide by eliminating inefficient investments.
According to Eatwell (2004) the collapse of the stock market in
2000 was the result of a coordination failure or change in investor
sentiment, and the rapid expansion of public debt since then served to
displace inefficient investments in the same way that the bubble did.
Viewed in this light, the large budget deficits of the Bush
administration can be interpreted as a welfare-improving response to
this market failure. But there is also a more "cynical"
interpretation, that is observationally equivalent to the
"benevolent" view. Under this interpretation the expansion of
public debt caused the collapse of the bubble, as the US government
tried to appropriate the value of the bubble from its US and foreign
owners.
White (2006) provides his own comments on the 1920 and 1990 stock
market bubbles and criticizes both fundamental approach in forward
looking assets and waves of pessimism and optimism driving investors
decisions and therefore creation of bubbles, however the author does not
provide any reasonable explanations of stock market bubbles and puts
more questions than answers.
There were also other examples of bubbles in stock markets. In the
autumn of 2002 stock prices of the biggest chain of rehabilitation hospitals in the United States dropped dramatically, after revealed
regulatory concerns. On the one hand this case can be put along with the
same events concerning Enron, WorldCom, etc. On the other hand, there
were differences concerning the reaction of headquarters--just weeks
before negative conclusions, which affected a fall of stock prices, the
chairman of HealthSouth Corporation sold 94 percent of his company.
There is a strong opinion, that the main reasons for this wave of
dramas, concerning, as we mentioned above, not only HealthSouth
Corporation, but also Enron, WorldCom was technology bubble. It is
well-recognized, that the technology bubble has induced, or has been
accompanied by, a number of new trends, one of which is the growth in
earnings manipulation. The enormous growth in earnings restatements
during the 1990s could be presented as evidence. The main underlying
forces that generate and fuel such a bubble, according to the opinion of
analysts, rely on three fundamental observations:
1) many investors are not fully rational and exhibit various
psychological biases in their financial decision-making. Also, some
investors may take reported earnings at face value, without looking
deeper into a firm's accounts;
2) investors' intrinsic overconfidence generates differences
of opinion, since at any given time investors overweigh their own
information and at the same time they underweigh others'
information.
3) usage of derivatives causes a wider range of possible price
speculation. Combination of these three processes allows the possibility
of speculation to occur in the market.
However, all observations do not provide the clear explanations of
the mechanism of stock market bubble formations, as the process itself
is too complex (Tvaronaviciene, Michailova 2006). The Logistic growth
models, as authors claim, can be applied to shed more light on stock
market bubble formations.
3. Capital accumulation models
Most frequently, in the cases when various financial problems occur
in relation to payments or cash rate at the given moment of time, or
when it is urgent to model the capital price, investments or any other
cash flows, the present or future value of capital is calculated. As a
rule, such calculations are based on the socalled formula of compound
interest (Bodie, Merton 2000). Consider:
K = [K.sub.0] x [r.sup.t], (1)
here: [K.sub.0] is the present capital value; K expresses the
future capital value or the capital value at the t moment of time; r
describes the coefficient of accumulation rate (r = 1 + i; here i is
interest rate) and t is accumulation duration expressed in time units
fixed in interest rate. Sometimes Equation (1) is called an exponential
function of capital accumulation.
Traditionally, Equation (1) is used to calculate the growth of
capital (population, product). However, much calculation may be
performed only until the capital growth is not restricted by external
factors (Merkevicius et al. 2006).
Capital cannot increase at an equal rate endlessly, the more so if
the system is completely or partially closed. When growing in such a
system, capital exhausts the limited resources in its environment. In
other words, it enters into self--competition which diminishes its
growth--the system gets 'satiated'.
It is assumed that in the given environment, capital may increase
up to a certain limit (in the given environment, only a particular
amount of capital not larger than the determined one may be invested).
The maximum rate of growth is [K.sub.m]. Then the interval of the
capital alteration, or growth (relatively, it may be considered as an
areal, or space of growth) is as follows [K.sub.0] [less than or equal
to] K [less than or equal to] [K.sub.m].
The growth of capital will be described by the logistic function of
growth (Girdzijauskas 2008). Consider:
K = [K.sub.m] x [K.sub.0] x [r.sup.t]/[K.sub.m] + [K.sub.0] x
([r.sup.t] - 1), (2)
here: [K.sub.0] is the present capital value; r defines the
accumulation rate coefficient and t is time expressed in the same units
as the time estimated in the interest rate of growth (in most cases, it
points to the whole periods of the interest rate recalculation).
It should be noted that if the maximum value of the product
[K.sub.m] increases and approaches infinity ([K.sub.m] [right arrow]
[infinity]), i.e. if for Equation (2) the limit [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] will be calculated, then, as it might have
been expected, Formula 2 will turn into an ordinary rule of compound
interest (1). Then, the formula of compound interest (1) will make a
separate case of the logistic accumulation function (2), when the
maximum capital rate [K.sub.m] is extremely high.
In frequent economic calculations, the present capital value rather
than the capital growth, i.e. its future value is calculated. Then the
logistic function of the present value is used (Girdzijauskas 2008).
Consider:
[K.sub.0] = [K.sub.m] x K/K + ([K.sub.m] - K) x [r.sup.t], (3)
here: [K.sub.0] is the present capital value; K expresses the
capital value at the t moment of time; r defines the accumulation
duration expressed in the time units fixed in interest rate. Actually,
the described expression is the formula of logistic discount.
4. Elasticity of the logistic internal rate of return to the
resources
It is often important to measure the "sensitivity" of the
function revealing the economic phenomenon to the alterations of a
particular variable. At first it might seem that an appropriate measure
of such sensitivity should be the fall of the function. However, the
fall of the function depends on the units by which the argument and the
function itself are measured. If the capital is measured by Euros, the
fall gets diminished 3.5 times. Therefore, in order to avoid the
recurrent consideration of the employed measurement units, it is
purposeful to apply the sensitivity measure that does not depend on
measurement units. In economics, such measure is called elasticity. The
elasticity of the function with respect to argument is an approximate
increase of the function in per cent (i.e. its growth or decrease) that
conforms to the increase of an independent variable in one per cent.
With respect to time capital elasticity may be expressed as the
ratio of time and capital multiplied by the fall of the capital
function. Elasticity is also convenient to be described with the use of
the function derivative.
It is assumed that the alteration of the independent variable (i.e.
argument) X of the function y = f(x) is Ax and the alteration of the
function Ay. Then the relative alteration (i.e. increase) of the
independent variable will make [DELTA]x/x, and the relative alteration
of the function will be [DELTA]y/y. When the function's relative
alteration is divided by the argument's relative alteration, the
approximate value of elasticity Ex(y) will be as follows:
[E.sub.x](y) [approximately equal to] [DELTA]y/y : [DELTA]x/x =
[DELTA]y/[DELTA]x x x/y. (4)
If in the analyzed interval the function y = f(x) has its
derivative, then
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
The obtained expression will be the elasticity of the function y =
f(x). Consider:
[E.sub.x](y) = x/y x dy/dx. (6)
With respect to argument (i.e. time) the function's elasticity
is the limit of the function's relative alteration divided by the
argument's relative alteration when the argument's alteration
approaches zero. To make it shorter, the function's elasticity is
the ratio of argument and function multiplied by the function's
derivative.
It should be stressed that the function's elasticity is
usually described by pointing out the agent with respect to which it is
calculated. For instance, in the theory of economics, the elasticity of
demand or supply to price, the demand's elasticity to income, etc.
is calculated.
Actually, the function whose module of elasticity is higher than 1,
is considered to be elastic. In case its module of elasticity is lower
than 1, the function is considered to be non-elastic. If it is equal to
1, the function demonstrates its single--unit elasticity.
Now the compound interest function's (1) elasticity to time
should be calculated. Since the rate of the function's alteration
is dK/dt = [K.sub.0] x [r.sup.t] x ln r, its elasticity will make:
[E.sub.t](K) = t x ln r. (7)
If the compound interest function (1) is replaced by its separate
case--the equation of natural growth K = [K.sub.0] x [e.sup.i x t]--its
elasticity will be as follows:
[E.sub.t](K) = t. (8)
It is obvious that the elasticity of the natural growth function to
time is equal to the value of the time from which it is calculated. This
function becomes elastic when t > 1.
Compound Interest Formula (1) is used to discount the sums when the
present rate [K.sub.0] is calculated. Since [K.sub.0] = K/[r.sup.t], the
elasticity of the present value to time will be as follows:
[E.sub.t](K) = -t x ln r. (9)
Hence the elasticity of the future and the present values of
compound interest differ only by their signs. Meanwhile, the elasticity
of the logistic growth function (2) to time is a little more complex. It
makes:
[E.sub.t](K) = ([K.sub.m] - [K.sub.0]) x ln [r.sup.t]/[K.sub.m] +
[K.sub.0] x ([r.sup.t] - 1). (10)
The elasticity of the logistic present value to time is as follows:
[E.sub.t]([K.sub.0]) = - ([K.sub.m] - K) x [r.sup.t] x ln r/K +
([K.sub.m] + K) x [r.sup.t]. (11)
To prove the possibility for the elasticity application during the
exploration of the economic bubbles, a particular investment project
should be analyzed.
It is assumed that the project will be realized within 5 years. At
the beginning of the first year 1 relative monetary unit is invested.
Later on, for five years in turn, an adequate part of the monetary unit
is invested--0.9; 0.8; 0.7; 0.6 and 0.5.
The project's income obtained annually is the same and equal
to 1 relative monetary unit. The project's internal returnability
may be calculated in the following way. For the analysis of the project
the most important is the total cash flow. Here the part of income is an
increasing sequence: 0.1; 0.2; 0.3; 0.4 and 0.5 of the relative monetary
unit each year. The sum total is positive and makes 0.5 of the monetary
unit.
With the use of Computer Calculator Microsoft Excel it is found out
that the project's internal rate of return is IRR = 0.12.
The analogical logistic internal rate of return will differ from
the calculated one and will depend on the amount of the capital
resources. For each particular limited capital [K.sub.m] it is found out
from the following equation:
LIRR = [5.summation over (j=1)] [K.sub.m] x [K.sub.j]/[K.sub.j] +
([K.sub.m] - [K.sub.j]) x [r.sup.j] - 1, (12)
here: LIRR is logistic internal rate of return; [K.sub.j] is the
jth member of the money flow (j also defines the accumulation duration
expressed in time units fixed in the interest rate i; j = [bar.1,5]), r
is accumulation rate coefficient with the interest rate i (r = 1 + i).
Then the dependence of the investment project's logistic
internal rate of return on the amount of the limited capital resources
is calculated. It should be noted that the dependence is further
presented in the form of the table (Table 1). To perform the analytical
research, the regression equation of this dependence should be worked
out. Consider:
It is assumed that LIRR = y. Then the regression curve equation of
the dependence of the internal rate of return on the amount of the
capital resources is as follows:
y = 0.12 + 0.0125 x [([K.sub.m] - 0.4).sup.-1.573].
The derivative of this function is worked out in the following way:
dy/d[K.sub.m] = -0.01966/[([K.sub.m] - 0.4).sup.2.573]
Then the elasticity of the internal rate of return to resources
will make:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (13)
here: [K.sub.m] > 0.4. When the limited capital is lower than
0.7904, the elasticity of the project's logistic internal rate of
return is higher than 1, which means that the internal rate of return
has become elastic (or sensitive).
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
With the further decrease of the limited capital and its
approaching the limited value that makes 0.4 of the relative monetary
unit, the elasticity turns to be as high as it is desired. It means that
the project itself turns into a price bubble. For instance, when
[K.sub.m] = 0.42, the value of elasticity found out on the basis of
Formula (6) makes 32 units; when [K.sub.m] = 0.41, the elasticity value
makes already 64 units. In other words, when the limited capital alters
by 0.01 of the relative monetary unit, the elasticity alters by
approximately 32 units. Then, on the theoretical level, it is possible
to illustrate the price bubble formation. On the practical level, the
price bubble may explode without having reached such high elasticity
values.
The analyzed example shows that the decrease of resources that is
more frequently noticed in a closed system considerably alters the
behaviour of the investment environment: with the decrease of the growth
recourses the internal rate of return increases. In turn, the growth of
the internal rate of return causes the critical increase of the
system's efficiency. The system becomes unstable so that with an
inconsiderable alteration of the value of the resource rate may destroy
the system itself. Hence the project's logistic internal rate of
return elasticity to the limited capital (Figure) shows the stability
degree of the forming stock market bubble. The very high increase of
internal rate of return was the main characteristic of stock price
bubbles manifested in 1920 and 1990. The application of logistic growth
models for economic bubbles analysis needs to be explored further
seeking to develop an effective tool for the prediction of stock and
other markets bubbles.
5. Conclusions
There are many explanations of economic and stock market bubbles
provided in scientific literature which are mainly based on fundamental
value approach, inflation, waves of pessimism and optimism driving
investors decisions in stock markets, etc., however all these approaches
do not provide clear explanations of the origin of stock market bubble
formations.
Exponential models are widely employed to model the alteration of
the permanently growing capital. However, such models are not always fit
for the practical use because of their insufficient accuracy and
convenience. Hence the growth of the capital may be modeled with the use
of the logistic growth models. Such logistic models of capital
accumulation reveal the dynamics of the capital growth more accurately.
Based on Logistic growth models the growth of the internal rate of
return on insvestments causes the critical increase of the system's
efficiency. The system becomes unstable and the inconsiderable
alteration of the value of the resource rate may destroy the system
itself. Hence the project's logistic internal rate of return
elasticity to the limited capital shows the stability degree of the
forming stock market bubble. The very high increase of internal rate of
return was the main characteristic of stock price bubbles manifested in
1920 and 1990.
The method of the logistic investment management allows for a new
treatment of the investment assessment and description of the reasons
for the possible unsuccessful investment realization. The estimation of
the degree of market saturation allows for a more accurate calculation
of the rate of return necessary for investment.
Received 9 August 2007; accepted 15 November 2008
References
Bodie, Z.; Merton, R. C. 2000. Finance. New Jersey: Cambridge
University Press. 592 p.
Caballero, R. J.; Hammour, M. L. 2002. Speculative growth. NBER Working Paper No. 9381. Available from Internet:
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w9381>.
Cochrane, J. H. 2002. Stocks as money: convenience yield and the
tech-stock bubble. NBER Working Paper No. 8987, Cambridge. Available
from Internet: <http://www.nber.org/papers/w8987>.
Eatwell, J. 2004. Useful bubbles, Contributions to Political
Economy 23: 35-47.
Ferreira, O. C. 1998. Capital accumulation in the Brazilian
economy, Economy and Energy 9: 1-24.
DeLong, J. B.; Magin, K. 2001. A short note on the size of the
Dot-Com bubble. NBER Working paper No. 8630. Available from Internet:
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w8630>.
Girdzijauskas, S. 2002. Logistiniai (ribiniai) kaupimo modeliai
[Logistic (marginal) accumulation models], Informacijos mokslai
[Information Sciences] 23: 95-102.
Girdzijauskas, S. 2008. Logistic theory of capital management:
deterministic methods, Transformations in Business and Economics 7,
2(14, Supplement A): 15-163.
Girdzijauskas, S.; Cepinskis, J.; Jurkonyte, E. 2007. Modern
accounting method in insurance tariffs--novelty on the insurance market,
Technological and Economic Development of Economy 13(3): 179-183.
Grundey, D. 2008. Application of sustainability principles in
economy, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(2):
101-106.
Kraay, A.; Ventura, J. 2005. The Dot-Com bubble, the Bush deficits,
and the U.S. current account. NBER Working paper No. 11543. Available
from Internet: <http://www.nber.org/papers/w121543>.
Merkevicius, E.; Garsva, G.; Girdzijauskas, S. 2006. A hybrid
SOM-Altman model for bankruptcy prediction, Lecture Notes in Computer
Science 3994: 364-371.
Pastor, L.; Veronesi, P. 2004. Was there a NASDAQ bubble in the
late 1990s? Available from Internet:
<faculty.chicagogsb.edu/lubos.pastor/research/bubble14www.pdf>.
Shone, R. 2001. An introduction to economic dynamic. London:
Cambridge University Press.
Sterman, J. D. 2000. Business dynamics: systems thinking and
modelling for a complex world. New York: Irwin/McGraw-Hill. 1008 p.
Streimikiene, D.; Esekina, B. 2008. EU emission reduction
strategies and their impact on atmospheric emissions in Lithuania,
Technological and Economic Development of Economy 4(2): 162-170.
Zavadskas, E. K. 2008. Beginning a new stage of development,
Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(3): 241-243.
White, E. N. 2006. Bubbles and busts: the 1990s in the mirror of
the 1920s. NBER Working Paper No. 12138. Available from Internet:
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w12138>.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Michailova, J. 2006. Factors affecting
securities prices: theoretical versus practical approach, Journal of
Business Economics and Management 7(4): 213-222.
DOI: 10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.45-51
Stasys Girdzijauskas (1), Dalia Streimikiene (2)
Vilnius University, Kaunas Faculty of Humanities, Muitines g. 11,
LT-44280 Kaunas, Lithuania
E-mails: (1)
[email protected]; (2)
[email protected]
Table 1. Dependence of the logistic internal rate of return
on the amount of resources
[K.sub.m] 0.497 0.5 0.51 0.52 0.55 0.6
LIRR 0.66 0.66 0.49 0.44 0.36 0.30
[K.sub.m] 0.68 0.8 1 2 20
LIRR 0.25 0.21 0.18 0.14 0.12