Minimum wages, on-the-job training, and wage growth.
Sicilian, Paul
1. Introduction
It has long been recognized that firms may react to imposition of a
legal minimum wage by reducing nonpecuniary attributes of jobs.
Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and Mincer (1981) suggest that, since
human capital models predict workers will pay for at least part of any
on-the-job training through reductions in wages, a binding minimum wage
will reduce training opportunities. They present similar empirical tests
of this hypothesis that, they argue, support the theory.
Though routinely cited as examples of the effects of binding
minimum wage constraints (e.g., Ehrenberg and Smith 1997), their tests
are unconvincing for theoretical reasons and because of data limitations
they faced. In fact, neither researcher had direct evidence on training.
Instead, they inferred the amount of on-the-job training received by
observing wage growth over a fixed period of time without accounting for
the possibility that individuals may change jobs during the period of
observation. Thus, the data they use do not allow one to be sure that
wage growth within the firm is lower on jobs starting at the minimum
wage. Lazear and Miller (1981) also attempt to measure the effects of
minimum wages on wage growth. Like the other researchers, they expect
that binding minimum wages may inhibit wage growth, though they do not
insist that reduced training is the only explanation for the expected
lower wage growth. based on their empirical work, they conclude that,
"There are no obvious retardation effects of the minimum wage on
wage growth" (p. 350). Comparing their empirical method and
findings to those of Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and Mincer (1981),
they argue that, "The lack of robustness of results across studies
suggests that the issue raised is one worthy of study, but one that has
not been shown to be important conclusively" (p. 378).
This paper uses data from the Employment Opportunities Pilot
Project (EOPP) to examine directly the relationships between minimum
wages, wage growth, and on-the-job training. We find that wage growth is
slower on minimum wage jobs than on other jobs. However, the amount of
training provided to workers on minimum wage jobs is not significantly
different than the amounts of training other low-wage workers receive.
Thus, the EOPP data indicate that, while workers on minimum wage jobs do
experience slower wage growth than other low-wage workers, this outcome
is not due to reduced on-the-job training.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next
section provides a critical review of the research on minimum wage
effects on wage growth and training. Section 3 discusses the EOPP data
and defines the variables used in our empirical procedures. Section 4
presents the results of our estimation, and the final section presents
our conclusions and suggestions for further research.
2. Previous Research
As mentioned above, there are three existing studies of the effects
of minimum wages on wage growth - Hashimoto (1982), Leighton and Mincer
(1981), and Lazear and Miller (1981).(1) All three use samples of young
men from the 1960s and/or early 1970s. Hashimoto uses the National
Longitudinal Survey (NLS), Lazear and Miller use both the NLS and the
National Longitudinal Study of the High School Class of 1972, and
Leighton and Mincer use both the NLS and the Panel Study of Income
Dynamics (PSID).
Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and Mincer (1981) explicitly attempt
to measure the effects of minimum wages on training. Their method -
using wage growth to proxy the amount of on-the-job training - has been
used by other researchers studying the effects of training (Lazear 1976;
Landes 1977). While this method is an ingenious attempt to get around
data limitations regarding on-the-job training, there are several
shortcomings to this research. First, human capital theory suggests that
the rate of wage growth for a given amount of training depends on the
proportion of that training that is specific and on the relative
bargaining power of the employer and employee (Hashimoto 1981). Thus,
different rates of wage growth do not necessarily imply different
amounts of on-the-job training. Moreover, several theories of
compensation suggest that wage growth may be independent of increases in
productivity. For example, Salop and Salop (1976) develop an adverse
selection model, which suggests that firms will offer back-loaded
compensation packages to attract workers with lower turnover
propensities. Also, principal-agent models argue that inclined earnings
profiles provide incentives for greater employee effort on the job
(Lazear 1979). As Lazear and Miller (1981) point out, even if there is
convincing evidence that wage growth is retarded by minimum wages, it
may not be because of reduced investments in human capital. Instead,
"the current retardation in wage growth may reflect minor shifting
of the age-earnings profile, paying out more of lifetime wealth to young
workers" (p. 353). Card and Krueger (1995) present evidence to this
effect using data from surveys of fast food restaurants in Texas. They
show that these employers neither delayed the time of the first raise
nor reduced the size of the raise in response to increases in the
minimum wage.
Finally, in both the Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and Mincer
(1981) studies, wage growth is measured as the change in wages observed
over the same fixed calendar time period for all individuals. Thus, wage
growth is observed at potentially very different points in each
person's tenure and, in fact, may represent wages at two different
jobs. Since human capital theory suggests that most training will occur
at or near the beginning of a job, the best test of the training
hypothesis would be to observe workers at the start of employment
spells. Because the EOPP includes direct and relatively detailed
measures of on-the-job training, we are able to avoid the disadvantages
of the indirect method described above.
3. Data
The EOPP is a two-wave survey of approximately 3000 firms conducted
in 1980 and 1982. This study uses the 1982 data. The firms in the EOPP
are concentrated in the South and Midwest(2) and are predominately small
and low-wage employers. Given the well-known differences in pay and
personnel policies between large and small employers, one should be
circumspect in generalizing the results presented in this paper.(3) The
survey directs the employer to consider "the last new employee your
company hired prior to August 1981" and asks questions dealing with
both "that person and the position he or she was hired to
fill." Wage information includes the current wage of the employee
(or, if the worker has left the firm, the wage at the time of the
separation) and the starting wage. Thus, we are able to measure wage
growth within the firm precisely. Moreover, we are able to determine
whether the employee started at the minimum wage.(4) The dummy variable MINIMUM WAGE is equal to one if the individual started at the minimum
wage. Also, to differentiate minimum wage jobs from other low-paying
jobs, we include two other starting wage dummy variables. BELOW MINIMUM
WAGE is equal to one if the starting wage is less than the minimum wage,
and JUST ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE is equal to one if the starting wage is no
more than 25 cents above the minimum wage.(5) Table 1, which presents
tabulations of starting wages by occupation and industry, shows that
both minimum wage and other low-wage jobs are concentrated in the
service and clerical occupations and in the service and retail
industries.
The EOPP provides relatively detailed information regarding
on-the-job training. Specifically, we know, during the first three
months the number of hours management, supervisors, and coworkers devote
to formal and informal training of the newly hired worker. TRAINING
INTENSITY is the sum of the first three months of training
activities.(6) Since not all workers [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED]
in our sample have completed three months with the firm, we include in
our training regressions a dummy variable - JOB TENURE MORE THAN 3
MONTHS - equal to one if the individual's tenure is greater than or
equal to three months.
Demographic variables contained in the EOPP include the
worker's SEX and his or her AGE at the time of hiring. EDUCATION is
defined as years of schooling completed when hired, while RELATED
EXPERIENCE is defined as the answer to the question "How many
[years] of experience in jobs that had some application to the position
did (name) have before (he/she) started working for your company?"
TENURE in years for those workers who are no longer with the firm is
given in the data. For those still employed by the firm, tenure can be
calculated using information regarding the worker's starting month
and year and the date of the survey.
Firm-wide data in the EOPP include the extent of unionization
within the firm and the firm's standard industrial classification
code. UNION is the "current percentage of nonsupervisory workers
that are covered by collective bargaining." We control for industry
in some specifications through use of dummy variables corresponding to
one-digit SIC codes and for occupation using dummy variables
corresponding to the job's Dictionary of Occupational Titles code.
While the EOPP does not provide an exact measure of plant size or firm
size, it does report the number of employees in all the firm's
establishments within the geographic site defined by the EOPP The log of
this number, FIRM SIZE, is included in our regressions.
We know at the time of the hiring whether the job was permanent,
temporary, or seasonal. PERMANENT is a dummy variable equal to one if
the job was permanent. The variable WEEKLY HOURS contains the
individual's usual weekly hours worked. Barron, Black, and
Loewenstein (1993) suggest that wages and on-the-job training are likely
to be affected by the amount of physical capital available to the
worker. The EOPP includes the question, "If it were purchased today
what would be the cost of the most expensive machine people in [this]
position work on or with?" The firm's answer can fall into one
of five categories: under $2000, $2000-$10,000, $10,000-$50,000,
$50,000-$200,000, over $200,000. We follow Barron and Bishop (1985) in
defining CAPITAL as the geometric mean of the interval given by the
firm.(7)
The major weakness of the EOPP is some missing demographic
variables for the worker. In particular, the data set has no information
regarding race, marital status, or the size of the worker's family,
if any. There is ample evidence in the existing empirical literature of
gender differences with regard to the determinants of and the returns to
training (e.g., Holtmann and Idson 1991; Lynch 1992; Barron, Black, and
Loewenstein 1993). Thus, we estimate separate equations for men and
women. We are somewhat concerned about how the omission of marital
status and family size data affects our ability to control for labor
force attachment, particularly since attachment to the labor force is
likely to be an important determinant of on-the-job training. We believe
that RELATED EXPERIENCE serves as a proxy for historical labor force
attachment. An additional control comes from the fact that the firm is
asked "How many weeks does it take a new employee hired for this
position to become fully trained and qualified if he or she has no
previous experience in this job, but has had the necessary
school-provided training." We follow Barron, Berger, and Black
(1993) in using responses to this question as a measure of JOB
COMPLEXITY. As O'Neill and Polachek (1993, p. 210) note, ". .
. investments requiting lengthy or otherwise costly training are less
likely to be undertaken by those who do not anticipate a long period of
market work." Hence, we use JOB COMPLEXITY as a proxy for labor
force attachment. Since Brown (1989) finds that nearly all wage growth
occurs during the training period, we include in the wage growth
equations the dummy variable TRAINING DONE, equal to one if the
individual's TENURE is greater than the number of weeks needed to
become fully trained in the job.
To create samples from the EOPP, we keep only those observations in
which the individual is between the ages of 16 and 65. Hires prior to
1978 are dropped to avoid problems associated with retrospective
information.(8) These restrictions leave us with 2984 observations.
Finally, for each regression, we drop all observations for which there
is not a complete set of variables.(9) This leaves us with samples of
between 1006 and 1188 for men and between 817 and 949 for women. Table 2
presents descriptive statistics for our sample. Since our sample
restrictions eliminate nearly a third of the original sample, we compare
the summary statistics of the excluded workers - found in Appendix 1 -
to our final sample of workers.(10) We find no appreciable differences
between our sample of workers and the excluded group.
Although the EOPP has more detailed training information than most
other data sets, it is useful to examine their validity.(11) In
particular, it would be reassuring to know whether our TRAINING
INTENSITY variable relates to other variables in our data in ways that
conform to our expectations. Our examination of the data reveals that,
as expected, TRAINING INTENSITY [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2 OMITTED] is
positively correlated with EDUCATION (r = 0.0697), TENURE (r = 0.0571),
and JOB COMPLEXITY (r = 0.1094) and negatively correlated with RELATED
EXPERIENCE (r = -0.0750) and AGE (r = -0.0568). Moreover, it is worth
noting that Lynch (1992) finds a relatively high degree of consistency
between the EOPP training data and similar data contained in the
National Longitudinal Survey of Youth.
In Table 3, we present, for various ranges of the starting wage,
mean levels of training, wage growth, and tenure, as well as the means
of some key worker characteristics such as age, education, and
experience. On average, men who start work in low-wage jobs are in less
complex jobs and are likely to receive fewer hours of training than
other workers. Wage growth for men in minimum wage jobs is considerably
less than the wage growth of other men. Both more years of education and
more years of previous experience are associated with higher starting
wages.
Women who start work at the minimum wage also seem to have somewhat
slower wage growth than other workers, though the difference is not as
pronounced. However, it appears that women who start at the minimum wage
are no less likely than other workers to receive training and that they
receive no fewer hours of training than other workers. In what follows,
we investigate these relationships more fully. Ultimately, we find the
patterns suggested by Table 3 to be quite consistent with our overall
conclusions.
4. Estimation
Wage Growth Equations
We start our formal analysis by estimating the effect of minimum
wages on wage growth. To estimate wage growth, we use a standard human
capital specification augmented by both the [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 3
OMITTED] starting wage dummy variables and, in some specifications, our
direct measure of on-the-job training. There is some controversy in the
literature regarding the proper measure of wage growth. Hashimoto (1982)
and Lazear and Miller (1981) both use percentage wage growth as their
dependent variable. Leighton and Mincer (1981), on the other hand, argue
that it is more proper to use absolute wage growth. They give two
reasons for this. First, the return to an amount of investment in human
capital (in this case, the amount of training) should be measured in
dollars rather than in percentages. Second, even if all workers in a
sample experienced identical levels of absolute wage growth, those hired
at the minimum wage and other low wages would tend to experience the
highest percentage gains in the wage. Thus, the use of percentage wage
growth on the left-hand side would increase the likelihood of finding a
minimum wage effect. The result is that "dollar growth provides a
more convincing test of the effect of the minimum wage on wage growth
than percentage growth" (Leighton and Mincer 1981, p. 164). In
fact, while they concentrate their discussion on the results from
estimating absolute wage growth, Leighton and Mincer also estimate
models using percentage wage growth as well as models with the current
wage as the dependent variable and the starting wage as a control
variable. Their conclusions are robust to their measure of wage growth.
We also estimate regressions using percentage wage growth and models of
the current wage, in levels and logs, on the starting wage, inter alia.
As described below, our conclusions are robust to the different
specifications.
We focus first on ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of wage
growth regressions omitting TRAINING INTENSITY. This allows us to
directly compare our findings to the previous research. Column 1 of
Table 4 presents these estimates for the men in our sample. We find that
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] men in minimum wage jobs experience
significantly less wage growth than men in other jobs. Calculated at the
means of the sample, the estimates in column 1 suggest that men with
starting wages equal to the minimum wage experience 47% lower wage
growth than men starting well above the minimum wage. Thus, our findings
are in line with Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and Mincer (1981) rather
than Lazear and Miller (1981).
For women (Table 4, column 4), wage growth is significantly lower
on all low-wage jobs than on jobs starting well above the minimum wage.
With industry and occupation controls included, we estimate that wage
growth is about 52% lower for women in MINIMUM WAGE jobs than for women
in jobs with starting wages more than 25 cents above the minimum wage.
While the point estimates imply that women on minimum wage jobs
experience slightly less wage growth than women on other low-wage jobs,
the estimated coefficients are not significantly different from one
another. Thus, while men in minimum wage jobs seem to have retarded wage
growth relative to men in other low-wage jobs, this difference is not
apparent for women.
To explore further the relationship between minimum wage
legislation and wage growth, we add TRAINING INTENSITY to the
specification. One potential problem with OLS estimation of wage growth
equations that include on-the-job training as an explanatory variable is
that on-the-job training is a choice variable. The training decision is
partially due to the employer and partially due to the worker through
his/her occupational and other preemployment choices. If, as a result,
unmeasured characteristics of jobs or workers associated with the
determination of on-the-job training are correlated with our measure of
the TRAINING INTENSITY, then the estimated coefficient on the training
variable will be biased, as it will be correlated with the error
term.(12)
To correct for this potential heterogeneity bias, we estimate our
wage growth equations using instruments for TRAINING INTENSITY. These
instruments are estimated from each of the Tobit specifications in Table
5 as the expected value of TRAINING INTENSITY conditional on receiving
training and are used in the corresponding wage growth equations.
Because this instrumental variable estimator is inefficient, we test for
the existence of heterogeneity bias using a Hausman (1978) specification
test.(13)
While the IV estimates, reported in Appendix 2, show a significant
negative effect of MINIMUM WAGE on the wage growth of both men and
women, TRAINING INTENSITY is never significant at the 10% level.(14)
Moreover, in each case, we fail to reject the null hypothesis of
equality between the OLS and IV coefficients. Given the lack of evidence
of unobserved heterogeneity in our estimates, we assume from this point
on that our sample is homogeneous and we concentrate on the OLS
estimates.(15)
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 5 OMITTED]
Columns 2 and 3 of Table 4 present estimates of wage growth
equations for men with TRAINING INTENSITY included. On-the-job training
is a positive and significant determinant of wage growth. This finding
is consistent with the bulk of empirical research on the wage effects of
on-the-job training (e.g., Lynch 1992; Booth 1993).(16) The estimates in
column 2 imply that every 10% increase in TRAINING INTENSITY is expected
to result in a 1.27% increase in wage growth, calculated at the means.
Including TRAINING INTENSITY in the wage growth equation attenuates
the estimated effect of minimum wages, though only marginally.
Nonetheless, minimum wage jobs continue to exhibit significantly less
wage growth than other jobs. The estimates in column 2 suggest that
minimum wage jobs experience 37% lower wage growth than jobs starting
well above the minimum wage.
For women, the estimated effects of minimum wages on wage growth
are essentially unchanged by including TRAINING INTENSITY. The point
estimates in column 6 of Table 4 imply that wage growth for women on
minimum wage jobs is about 44% lower than for women in jobs starting
well above the minimum wage, but once again, the estimated coefficient
on MINIMUM WAGE is not significantly different than the coefficients on
the other low-wage dummy variables. We find no significant effect of
TRAINING INTENSITY on women's wage growth. Apparently, therefore,
even if minimum wage legislation reduced women's training
opportunities, the estimates from Table 4 suggest that this would not
significantly impact women's wage growth.
As stated above, we estimated the wage growth equations using
percentage wage growth as well as regressions of the current wage on the
starting wage and our other control variables. Appendix 3 presents the
estimated coefficients for the starting wage dummy variables from these
regressions as well as the F-tests for significant differences between
MINIMUM WAGE and the other low-wage dummy variables. As can be seen,
these specifications tell essentially the same story as the absolute
wage growth regressions reported in Table 4. Namely, minimum wage jobs
exhibit significantly less wage growth for men but not for women.(17)
On-the-Job Training
Having established that the minimum wage is indeed associated with
reduced wage growth, particularly for men, we now use the direct
measures available in the EOPP to determine whether there is also an
observable relationship between holding a minimum wage job and the
quantity of on-the-job training received. We want to be confident that
these estimates focus on the correct question, namely: For otherwise
similar jobs, do training and wage growth differ for minimum wage versus
nonminimum wage jobs? Failing to control for potential sources of
individual-specific heterogeneity may cause our point estimates to be
seriously biased. Thus, we make every effort in our estimation to avoid
unobserved individual-specific heterogeneity.
It is likely that employers will respond to a minimum wage by
hiring better qualified applicants. These workers would need less
training since they presumably bring with them human capital obtained in
previous jobs. If we did not control for RELATED EXPERIENCE, our
estimates could potentially overstate the negative impact of minimum
wages on training.
As discussed above, JOB COMPLEXITY is included as a control for
labor market attachment. This is an important control if workers in less
complex jobs are, on average, more weakly attached to the labor force.
If these workers tend to end up in low-paying jobs, then omitting JOB
COMPLEXITY would cause the effects of the starting wage dummy variables
to be overstated.
To the extent that these variables capture what would otherwise be
unobserved worker heterogeneity, omitting them from the training
equation would seriously bias our estimated coefficients. Our model,
therefore, tests for differences in on-the-job training even when we
hold constant prior accumulations of human capital and labor force
attachment.
Other variables in the TRAINING INTENSITY regression include human
capital variables, EDUCATION, and AGE and firm-specific and
position-specific variables, MINIMUM WAGE, BELOW MINIMUM WAGE, JUST
ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE, PERMANENT, In(FIRM SIZE), CAPITAL, UNION, WEEKLY
HOURS, and JOB TENURE GREATER THAN 3 MONTHS.
Because a substantial portion of our sample received no training,
we use Tobit regressions to estimate on-the-job training equations.(18)
The estimated equations are reported in Table 5. For men, MINIMUM WAGE
is estimated to have a significant negative effect on on-the-job
training. Importantly, however, F-tests (reported at the bottom of Table
5) show there is no significant difference between the quantity of
on-the-job training received by workers in minimum wage jobs and the
amount of training received by workers in other low-paying jobs.
Apparently, what we observe is a low-wage effect on on-the-job training
rather than just a minimum wage effect. For women, MINIMUM WAGE is
estimated to have no effect on TRAINING INTENSITY, even with the
occupation and industry control variables omitted.
JOB COMPLEXITY is a significant determinant of training for both
men and women, though the magnitude of the effect of JOB COMPLEXITY is
considerably larger for women. This is consistent with our
interpretation of this variable as a measure of labor force attachment.
We expect labor force attachment to be a less important determinant of
men's on-the-job training since there is less variability in
men's attachment to the labor force. It is worth noting that the
women in our sample are represented disproportionately in jobs that are
less complex, which is an indication of women's weaker labor force
attachment.
Our estimates lead us to tell very different stories about the
relationships between minimum wage jobs, on-the-job training, and wage
growth for men and for women. For men, it appears that being in a
minimum wage job - or in any other low wage job - means that a worker
will receive fewer hours of on-the-job training than more highly paid
workers and that this leads to lower wage growth since hours of TRAINING
INTENSITY is an important determinant of wage growth. Moreover, it
appears that, even when the effect of TRAINING INTENSITY on wage growth
is accounted for, workers in minimum wage jobs experience slower wage
growth than other workers. For women, we find that workers in minimum
wage jobs receive as much training as other workers and that, in any
event, TRAINING INTENSITY does not influence wage growth.
5. Summary and Conclusions
We find that minimum wage jobs exhibit less wage growth than other
jobs. This finding is stronger for men than for women. Our results are
consistent with the research of Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and Mincer
(1981). Nonetheless, our conclusions are more in line with Lazear and
Miller (1981), that is, we find no evidence of a unique minimum wage
effect on training opportunities. The process of wage determination for
men appears to be consistent with human capital theory in that
on-the-job training has a significant impact on wage growth. However, we
find no evidence that training has an impact on women's wages.
Our conclusions suggest that the indirect method of proxying
training with wage growth can be misleading, as it fails to distinguish
whether the reduced wage growth of workers in minimum wage jobs results
from their receiving less training than other low-wage workers or
whether it is strictly a result of the wage determination process.
Future research should attempt to gauge the determinants of wage growth
on the job. In particular, empirical studies into the exact relationship
between on-the-job training and wage growth and the causes for gender
differences would be valuable.
[TABULAR DATA FOR APPENDIX 1 OMITTED]
[TABULAR DATA FOR APPENDIX 2 OMITTED]
Appendix 3
Minimum Wage Effects Using Alternative Wage Growth Measures (White
standard errors)
Dependent
Variable Men Women
% [Delta] Wage(a) MINIMUM WAGE -0.0169 0.0114
(-1.253) (-0.702)
BELOW MINIMUM WAGE 0.0914 0.0291
(3.164) (1.326)
JUST ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE 0.0363 0.0008
(1.774) (0.061)
F-test: p-value: MINIMUM
WAGE = BELOW
MINIMUM WAGE 0.0001 0.0790
F-test: p-value: MINIMUM
WAGE = JUST ABOVE
MINIMUM WAGE 0.0116 0.4772
Current Wage(a) MINIMUM WAGE -32.338 -23.081
(-4.178) (-2.244)
BELOW MINIMUM WAGE -5.997 -22.317
(-0.498) (-2.082)
JUST ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE -15.289 -20.196
(-1.398) (-2.581)
F-test: p-value: MINIMUM
WAGE = BELOW
MINIMUM WAGE 0.0135 0.9455
F-test: p-value: MINIMUM
WAGE = JUST ABOVE
MINIMUM WAGE 0.0930 0.7600
ln(Current Wage)(a) MINIMUM WAGE -0.0678 -0.0447
(-4.658) (-2.461)
BELOW MINIMUM WAGE 0.0263 -0.0288
(0.994) (-1.330)
JUST ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE -0.0138 -0.0290
(-0.660) (-1.899)
F-test: p-value: MINIMUM
WAGE = BELOW
MINIMUM WAGE 0.0003 0.4640
F-test: p-value: MINIMUM
WAGE = JUST ABOVE
MINIMUM WAGE 0.0096 0.3623
t-statistics are in parentheses.
a The set of control variables is the same as in Table 5 with
starting wage and industry and occupation controls included.
This is a revised version of a paper presented at the Western
Economic Association International meetings. The authors wish to thank
Mark Schweitzer, William Ferguson, William Boal, two anonymous referees,
and the editor for helpful comments on earlier drafts.
1 Note that, in their paper, Lazear and Miller (1981) refer to
prepublication versions of both the Hashimoto (1982) and Leighton and
Mincer (1981) papers.
2 Survey sites included firms from Alabama, Colorado, Florida,
Kentucky, Louisiana, Ohio, Texas, Washington, Wisconsin, and Virginia.
3 On the differences between large and small firms, see inter alia.
Brown, Hamilton, and Medoff (1990).
4 The NLS and PSID, by contrast, do not provide information on
starting wages.
5 Alternatively, we defined ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE as equal to one if
the starting wage was no more the 50 cents above the minimum wage. No
conclusions were changed by this alternative definition.
6 We note that this variable has a maximum value of 1200 hours for
women and 1400 hours for men, implying a maximum of about 100 hours of
training per week for women and 117 hours per week for men during the
first three months of employment. We assume that these large values
imply that several employees spent time with the trainee simultaneously,
though we are still circumspect about their validity. To limit the
effect of the few extremely large values of TRAINING INTENSITY on our
results, we estimated equations using the full sample and,
alternatively, with the sample truncated above 480 hours of training.
This truncation eliminates less than 2% of the sample for both women and
men and has no effect on our findings.
7 For the largest category, CAPITAL is set equal to $250,000.
8 Thus, the sample consists of workers who started their jobs
between 1978 and 1981. The minimum wage was increased in January in each
of these years. It was raised to $2.65 from $2.30 in 1978, to $2.90 in
1979, to $3.10 in 1980, and to $3.35 in 1981. Approximately 2% of
workers in the sample started their jobs in 1978, 8% in 1979, 17% in
1980, and 73% in 1981.
9 There is one exception: Because of the large numbers of missing
values for the variable WEEKLY HOURS, rather than drop observations, we
use the modified zero-order regression method described in Maddala
(1977); that is, in our regression analysis, we set missing observations
on weekly hours to zero and include a dummy variable equal to one if
weekly hours is missing and equal zero otherwise.
10 The variables with the most missing observations are STARTING
WAGE (286 missing), CURRENT WAGE (307 missing), and TRAINING INTENSITY
(363 missing).
11 See Barron, Berger, and Black (1997) for evidence on the
validity of data regarding on-the-job training.
12 Another potential problem is that, since the minimum wage was
increasing during the period of observation, individuals who were hired
at the minimum wage and who were still earning the minimum wage in 1981
(or at the time of separation) may have received wage increases simply
because of increases in the minimum wage. In an alternative
specification (not presented here), we estimated wage growth equations
omitting these individuals. None of our conclusions were affected by
this omission.
13 The null hypothesis is that plim([[Beta].sub.OLS] -
[[Beta].sub.IV]) = 0, where [[Beta].sub.OLS] and [[Beta].sub.IV] are
alternative estimators of the parameter vector [Beta]. Under the null,
[[Beta].sub.OLS] is consistent and efficient with asymptotic covariance
matrix [V.sub.OLS]. [[Beta].sub.IV], with asymptotic covariance matrix
[V.sub.IV], is consistent under both the null and alternative
hypotheses, though it is inefficient. The test statistic suggested by
Hausman (1978), ([[Beta].sub.OLS] - [[Beta].sub.IV])[prime]([V.sub.IV] -
[V.sub.OLS]) 1([[Beta].sub.OLS] - [[Beta].sub.IV]), is asymptotically
chi-square with degrees of freedom equal to rank([V.sub.IV] -
[V.sub.OLS]).
14 While the wage growth equations omit CAPITAL, AGE, and JOB
COMPLEXITY and are aided by the nonlinearity of the estimation procedure
for the instruments, we suspect that collinearity between our
instruments and the other right-hand side variables may be at least
partially responsible for the insignificance of TRAINING INTENSITY.
15 As an alternative check for heterogeneity, we follow Lynch
(1992). Booth (1993), and Veum (1995), among others, by using a Heckman
correction for self-selection (Heckman 1979). This procedure uses the
inverse Mills' ratio from a probit regression estimating the
probability of receiving training as a proxy for the unobservables in
the subsequent wage growth regression. Our findings using this method
are consistent with those discussed above: The inverse Mills' ratio
is never significant, which suggests that sample heterogeneity bias is
unlikely to affect our estimates.
16 A recent exception to this general conclusion, however, is
Levine (1993). who finds no evidence that high returns to tenure are
associated with higher than average levels of training.
17 In fact, two of the specifications tell exactly this story. The
percentage wage growth equation is a bit different. MINIMUM WAGE in this
specification is negative but statistically insignificant. BELOW MINIMUM
WAGE and JUST ABOVE MINIMUM WAGE are positive and significant.
Nonetheless, F-tests indicate that minimum wage jobs exhibit
significantly less wage growth than other low-wage jobs.
18 About 8% of men and 7% of women in our sample received no formal
or informal training during their first three months of employment.
References
Barron, John M., and John Bishop. 1985. Extensive search, intensive
search, and hiring costs: New evidence on employer hiring activity.
Economic Inquiry 23:363-82.
Barron, John M., Mark C. Berger, and Dan A. Black. 1993. Do workers
pay for on-the-job training? Unpublished paper, Purdue University and
University of Kentucky.
Barron, John M., Mark C. Berger, and Dan A. Black. 1997. How well
do we measure training? Journal of Labor Economics 15(part 1):507-28.
Barron, John M., Dan A. Black, and Mark A. Loewenstein. 1993.
Gender differences in training, capital, and wages. The Journal of Human
Resources 28:343-64.
Booth, Alison L. 1993. Private sector training and graduate
earnings. The Review of Economics and Statistics 75:164-70.
Brown, Charles, James Hamilton, and James Medoff. 1990. Employers
large and small. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Brown, James N. 1989. Why do wages rise with tenure? American
Economic Review 79:971-91.
Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 1995. Myth and measurement: The
new economics of the minimum wage. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Ehrenberg, Ronald G., and Robert S. Smith. 1997. Modern labor
economics. Reading, PA: Addison-Wesley Educational Publishers.
Hashimoto, Masanori. 1981. Firm-specific human capital as a shared
investment. American Economic Review 71:475-81.
Hashimoto, Masanori. 1982. Minimum wage effects on training on the
job. American Economic Review 72:1070-87.
Hausman, Jerry A. 1978. Specification tests in econometrics.
Econometrica 46:1251-71.
Heckman, James J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification
error. Econometrica 47:153-61.
Holtmann, Alphonse G., and Todd L. Idson. 1991. Employer size and
on-the-job training decisions. Southern Economic Journal 58:339-55.
Landes, Elisabeth M. 1977. Sex-differences in wages and employment:
A test of the specific human capital hypothesis. Economic Inquiry
15:532-8.
Lazear, Edward P. 1976. Age, experience and wage growth. American
Economic Review 66:548-58.
Lazear, Edward P. 1979. Why is there mandatory retirement? Journal
of Political Economy 87:1261-84.
Lazear, Edward P., and Frederick H. Miller. 1981. Minimum wage
versus minimum compensation. In Report of the Minimum Wage Study
Commission, volume 5. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office,
pp. 347-80.
Leighton, Linda, and Jacob Mincer. 1981. The effects of minimum
wages on human capital formation. In The economics of legal minimum
wages, edited by Simon Rottenberg. Washington, DC: American Enterprise
Institute, pp. 155-73.
Levine, David I. 1993. Worth waiting for? Delayed compensation,
training, and turnover in the United States and Japan. Journal of Labor
Economics 11:724-52.
Lynch, Lisa. 1992. Private sector training and the earnings of
young workers. American Economic Review 82:299-312.
Maddala, G. S. 1977. Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill.
O'Neill, June, and Solomon Polachek. 1993. Why the gender gap
in wages narrowed in the 1980's. Journal of Labor Economics
11:205-28.
Salop, Joanne, and Steven Salop. 1976. Self-selection and turnover
in the labor market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 90:619-27.
Veum, Jonathan R. 1995. Sources of training and their impact on
wages. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 48: 812-26.